• <tr id="yyy80"></tr>
  • <sup id="yyy80"></sup>
  • <tfoot id="yyy80"><noscript id="yyy80"></noscript></tfoot>
  • 99热精品在线国产_美女午夜性视频免费_国产精品国产高清国产av_av欧美777_自拍偷自拍亚洲精品老妇_亚洲熟女精品中文字幕_www日本黄色视频网_国产精品野战在线观看 ?

    The Meaning and Madness of Money: A Semio-Ecological Analysis

    2017-11-02 07:09:04PerAageBrandt
    Language and Semiotic Studies 2017年3期

    Per Aage Brandt

    Case Western Reserve University, USA

    The Meaning and Madness of Money: A Semio-Ecological Analysis

    Per Aage Brandt

    Case Western Reserve University, USA

    In this paper, I propose an overall model of the semantic and semiotic functions of money and capital forms, based on an ecological view of human activity and a theory of the origin of money (coined precious metals). Themeaningof money is replaced in a structured human perspective, and a critical discussion is outlined on the grounds of the material and capital flows and functions identified. Themadnessof money follows from the separation of economy and ecology. That madness causes serious damage, especially under certain circumstances that the structural analysis can identify. Finally I add some new considerations on the psycho-semiotic implications of the analysis. The societal structure discussed can be interpreted in terms that have strikingly direct correspondence to those describing semiotic aspects of language and the human psyché, where the concepts of meaning and madness are immediately pertinent.

    semio-ecology, money origins, socio-semiotics, the money sign, the symbolic order

    1. Ecological Prerequisites

    Monetary signs not only ‘signify’ abstract value but also possess a performative force rooted in their substantiation, that is, rooted in the fact that theirsubstanceof expression, to use the linguist Louis Hjelmslev’s term, is, at least in their basic manifestation as coins,but even still in their indirect manifestations, singularized as material objects.1Their“form of expression” cannot be separated from their “substance of expression”. The act of ‘giving signs’ is normally participative (the giver does not ‘lose’ what he gives, he just shares it), whereas giving money, therefore, isseparativegiving (moving singular material objects from one proprietor to another). This unique condition of monetary signs—money and its generalization: capital—is therefore still a serious challenge to semiotic theory. The understanding of performative force in speech acts offers a similar difficulty,based on their ritual abolition of the distinction between sign and thing in illocutionary uses of language.2Economics, the mathematics of monetary practices, is of little help in treating this challenge, in so far as it builds on the assumption that this mysterious object condition of the existence of money signs simply holds by definition; it is taken as an axiom, which should not be explained but just taken for granted and then analyzed in its current contexts.3

    In this essay, I will present an alternative, namely a semiotic and ecological, or semioecological, view of the problem of understanding money. I will ignore the axiom that the existence of money should just be taken for granted, and instead start from basic ecological considerations, supplemented by a semiotic approach to the issue.

    As the French philosopher Georges Bataille pointed out in a metaphysical moment,the living nature and the existence of human civilizations, are results of the practically infinite, generous, unrequited, entropic ‘giving’ of the sun, which on our planet causes anegentropicprocess calledlife.4If we follow Bataille and think of the entropic temporal flow of matter and energy as one immense stream, we may imagine the negentropic movement that humans and all other living beings are involved in, as a local reverse stream, or rather a number of local reverse negentropic streams, branching off from the main entropic flow. These negentropic streams finallyreturnto the main, entropic flow and thus form anecological loop. The return happens because death, decay, and waste make these negentropic movements spatially and temporally finite; new negentropic processes must start from the local death, decay, and waste of the former processes. This ecological loop is therefore never a trivial given; life is fragile and abruptly ends if it cannot feed on a nature that includes life’s own litter.

    Fig. 1. A negentropic loop

    Entropy universally increases, but locally decreases where living matter emerges. Life thus consists in a loop by which the universal run towards chaos is momentarily halted and patterns of organization grow, until death and decay resume the universal tendency.This is the elementary general framework I suggest as a general prerequisite of the development of a semio-ecological analysis. When life emerges, it lays the ground for organic species, and again for human life, which feeds on life in general, and on life’s decay and litter. In the case of humans, however, from the moment civilizations emerge,an empirical analysis easily distinguishes three principal (sub-negentropic) off-branchings and sub-loops, corresponding to three standard levels of social organization. We can in fact superimpose three negentropic sub-loops in the case of human civilizations.

    A first ecological sub-loop is initiated by our direct extraction and consumption of organic matter and water: vegetables, fruits, crops, animals—elements whose preparation mainly presupposes access to soil, water, wind, and fire, and a certain technique—hunting, fishing, gathering, sheltering, and then agriculture. This basicorganic loophas its own ecology, of course; crops must be kept growing on viable qualities of soil, and so on. Water, soft or salt, must be kept clean enough to remain a fishing environment or a source of watering and drinking. Firewood must be renewable. Deterioration and devastation are always threatening possibilities. Civilizations are ecologically vulnerable,as ethnology shows. Basic ecological consciousness, as found in tribal societies, grows on this essentialorganicloop, and may extend to the following two loops.

    A second loop extracts energy and raw materials allowing further elaboration of provisions, securing life conditions, and creating tools and means to satisfy expanding functional needs of collective life: we may call it thetechnical loop. Systematic production and distribution of artefacts (tools, machines, ships, weaponry) and other complex goods thus require extendedextractionof energy, stone, iron, wood, building materials, raw materials for all kinds of production and construction: production facilities,infrastructure (roads, bridges, means of transportation and communication), social institutions, marketplaces, shops and workshops, homes and urban settings. Technical production, maintenance, repair, renewal, and development of the entire space of work and exchange, increase the consumption of energy and many sorts of material. Strategies for the disposal and treatment of waste and refuse are again never trivial in view of maintaining a local habitat and a local population’s health and growth. The technical loop differs from the organic loop by its most prominent effect, urbanization, with its dumping sites and cemeteries.

    Finally, a third,symbolic loopalways extracts exquisite elements from nature for transcendent ‘spiritual’ reasons: precious and rare metals and minerals, gold, silver, copper,marble, jade, gemstones, are extracted for decorative and symbolic uses related to the erection of palaces and temples, with their adornments, imagery and statues, monuments,that is, for ceremonial purposes of many kinds, sacred or profane. In all larger historical societies, religious or profane displays of social power constitute an overall category ofsymbolicconstructivity and activity that shapes social life by providing overarching authority, mythology, emotional coherence, bringing both mystery and principles of ‘value’and forms of legitimacy—forms of ‘beauty’, ‘truth’, ‘justice’, and ‘morality’—to the entire complex of practices implied by collective life.5Taking care of the need for collective identity is an essential symbolic task of the nominal ruler, the sovereign. Taking care of deaths, births, and individual or collective alliances, is an essential symbolic task of the religious category. So we may call this particular stream thesymbolic loop. Symbolicity culturally seals the social formation as a whole. The negative output, or product, of the symbolic loop includes aggressive ideology and its consequence, warfare and destruction.In the contemporary world civilization, the symbolic loop still involves imagery and behaviors expressing the typical ‘spiritual’ endeavors embodied in sovereignty, and religion.

    These three negentropic, looping streams, all branching off from the main entropic flow and returning to it, can be represented as superimposed levels ofsubstantial and formal social life. The substantial differences from level to level will correspond to formal differences in the regulations and concepts appearing at the three levels. I hypothesize that the stratified flow model thus obtained is, so far, generally valid for human social formations throughout our prehistorical and historical civilizations, whether huntergatherer-tribal, agricultural-feudal, agri-theocratic, capitalo-industrial, or otherwise formalized.

    Fig. 2. The organic, the technical, and the symbolic loops on the entropic flow

    The three extraction-based loops will further correspond to three levels of vital social activity and life forms: in a very elementary social formation, that oforganic producers:agents in agriculture, fishing, hunting, gathering, etc.; that oftechnical producers:craftsmen, workers, engineers, administrators, traders, social and commercial agents; and that ofsymbolic producers: chiefs, rulers, politicians, intellectuals, artists, priests, and bankers.

    Between the three loops, there will always be many sorts of exchange, especially of products from one level serving on another level, both upwards and downwards. It is further necessary to consider the institutions that the constant activities on each level and between them create, as if by sedimentation, and which slowly but surely emerge by the nature of things, namely the needs that the activities themselves generate: needs for norms and maintenance of means, moral and technical. We can consider them as the modes ofstasisalong or within the flows, and it is possible to postulate a finite set of such major categories ofstasis,or‘establishments’—which may differ in many ways and in their relative importance, depending on the specific structures developed in specific cultures and forms of social production. Here follows my suggested list of default instances of this kind: six elementary categories of stasis.

    (1) Firstly, things like assuring the access to water, shelter, protection, construction wood and firewood, a territory of operation, require concrete collaborative measures,certain elementarycommunitarysystemsfor sharing necessary burdens and possible outcomes. This is the rudiment that may evolve into the network of institutions we now call the modern nation State. The elementary communitary instance primarily connects and interacts with the organic and the technical flows.

    (2) Secondly, organic products are immediately exchanged and distributed within a population according to some principles allowing the sharing of food, services, and basic goods. A community must therefore create and maintain pathways and places, where transportation, presentation and exchange of such entities can happen. We may call such accessible places, in a very elementary sense, foodmarkets.

    (3) Thirdly, as mentioned, we may acknowledge the stasis of urbanization, the creation of cumulative habitats where systematic technical production and products (artefacts)can be sheltered and connected (workshops, factories, storages), and where larger-scale social and cultural communication can happen. This ‘public’ sphere of urbanized activity includes the social accumulation of material goods and corresponding ‘wealth’, and the display thereof. Material wealth in turn leads to the development of abstract juridical concepts of property: principles of ownership, ‘private’ or ‘public’, passed down through generations and expressed by real estate; legal charters that allow private interests to emerge within the public domain.6

    (4) Exchanges on the level of ‘property’ lead to higher orders of distribution and market formation. On this level, real estate, land, and human beings (workers, women,slaves) are among thegoodsexchanged. The modern labor market is one of the aspects of this instance of the market; but much else is of course bound to happen before we get that far. This level is where production becomes industrial and capitalistic in the basic sense,and where the marxian theory of Capital, surplus value, profit, and subsequent class struggle then relevantly applies. Here is where societies acquire their so-called political economies, to be distinguished from their ‘general economies’ in Bataille’s sense, which includes all three levels.

    (5 and 6) On the third stream, the symbolic one, there are two universally unfolding forms of stasis. One is what we call the instance ofsovereignty, the place and institution of the ruler, the incarnation of the privilege and physical power to make binding decisions for entire populations on a territory and to declare wars: to define a ‘country’, and later,a ‘nation’, or even an ‘empire’. Physically, this stasis is expressed by lavish buildings, displays of provocative architecture with monumental dimensions and emphatic use of extracted and preferably rare and costly materials. The other form is the materialization ofreligion, the equally provocative and awe-inducing temple, which in modern societies,especially after the introduction and generalization of the use of money, is doubled by a parallel variant, the bank.7

    The following graph summarizes this simplified analysis of stases in the formation of a shared human reality. There is of course much more interaction between these instances than shown by the arrows of the graph. The idea is that an elementary deep-structure like the one proposed here must underlie the specification of distinct social formations,modes of production, and politico-economic structures and conjunctures, making them comparable. The contrasts between an isolated tribal society and a modern industrial society are evidently huge, but my claim is that we need a materialistic, ‘pre-structured’ecological basis like the one sketched out in this model to be able to structurally and more precisely specify and understand the differenthistoricalformations. History would thus be the temporal unfolding of a largely pre-determined structure.

    Fig. 3. Three strata and six stasis categories in the formation of social reality

    The three basic streams articulate the presupposed human population, a part of which is mainly active on the organic level, whereas other parts are active on the technical level of production; a much smaller part is active on the symbolic level, where power and sacredness are fabricated. Hence the intuitive model of a society as a pyramid. A population8will become a class or caste society if the level of activity, in terms of strata,of one generation is transferred to and thus inherited by subsequent generations. The access or non-access to property and sovereignty is then of course particularly important to the social status of a population segment. And as Marx and Engels stated, theextension of private ownershipof collectively produced products is one of the preconditions of the formations we call capitalistic. However, a prerequisite of the same magnitude is the existence and functionality ofmoney.

    2. Money

    There are reasons to believe that the phenomenon and the extended use of money, in the form of coins, emerge during the so-called Axial Age9, and that the religious instance (6,above) is directly involved.10Precious materials and, in particular,metalsare first used for the adornment of iconic representations of rulers and divinities (statues, imagery).These metals, gold, silver, electrum, bronze etc., are thereby—namely through the magical contact with the artistically embodied sacred entity—rendered even more precious, and are then, we suggest, interpreted as inheriting and containing the power of the divinities they adorn and magically touch. The priests discover that they can make poeple work for them by ‘paying’ them with these metallic items. Then the priests can‘lend’ people certain quantities of them for similar purposes, but against mortgage.They acquire an inherentprotective value11that makes them desirable in social life,in the shape of artistic adornments, and then in the shape of smallcoinscarrying the signs of a ruler who may in principle be seen as guaranteeing their metallic authenticity and volume. The ascribed inherent ‘value’ of pieces of such metal of equal weight and authenticity is then relatively equal and stable. The temple is originally the place where such money is coined and issued, and where larger quantities or amounts of ‘monetary’value is kept, hence the historical link between (ancient) temples and (modern) banks.But of course, the efficiency of these shining items is proven outside the temples, and especially in marketplaces on lower social levels. The use of uniform metallic units containing the abstract, imaginary property ofprotectingits owner is reinforced by the practical demonstration: in fact, the more you acquire of these entities, the better off you are.12You can exchange them for goods, services, including services of material protection. The semantics of money is in fact self-reinforcing.13However, let us not forget that trade, distribution, and accounting may well be much older than money. The first manifestations of writing, from the eighth century BC, namely the token systems found by Schmandt-Besserat14, are dedicated to counting kept animals, and therefore probably to the ‘a(chǎn)ccounting’ of such animals, own or owed. We know that cattle can be used as trading equivalents, or ‘capital’15, as seen from the Roman distinctionpecuniaversusfamilia, “small cattle” versus “big cattle”, the latter not used for ordinary trade but for more radical investments. When money filters into the practices of exchange, maybe five millennia into the agricultural societies emerging after the end of the last glaciation,something radically new happens to social life and cultural activity: a huge growth of societies under unifying rulers, and the beginning of monotheism (such as early zoroastrianism).16Both may be causally related to the way social formations are slowly and gradually permeated on all levels by the same massively and intensely repeated symbolic references. The next version of the stratification graph shows the principle (fig. 4). We may therefore distinguish three forms of monetary capital: 1) the concrete exchange-based, organic and reproductive capital, 2) the investment-based productive capital, and 3) the speculation-based financial, or symbolic capital17.In a sense, the third, symbolic level of monetary practice is primordial, since money originates there, if I am right; so, in the same sense, financial capital is a primordial form of money.18But as early religious and law texts illustrate, it is immediately used for buying work force, services, goods, and of course food. On the organic level, it constitutes thereproductive capitalthat circulates between food markets and income from paid work or sold products; small communitary capital formations—created by the invention oftaxes—cover the necessary infrastructure, education initiatives (schools), health-improving initiatives etc. The finality of this basic circulation of money is evidently thereproduction of human lifein the framework of various sorts of households: the simple meaning of the termoiko-nomy,19which is further used as a (problematically inaccurate and misleading,hence ideological) metaphor for the political “economy” of entire societies.

    Fig. 4. The three forms of monetary capital (in blue on the graph): reproductive, productive, and financial

    On the technical level, theproductive capitaloffers a different form of monetary circulation, and a different set of semantic concepts. Here, money can be stocked in‘property’ and can be ‘invested’ in industrious or industrial processes of paid work whose products are sold on the market of goods, so that the circular effect of ‘making money’by organizing production and distribution based on proletarian20workers paid by the money just ‘made’, that is, the surplus value ingeniously described by Karl Marx, can createprofitto reinvest, to stock in property, or to place in ‘speculative’ enterprises on the higher, symbolic level. If a section of the population cannot access the technical level as proprietors, it becomes in fact a ‘proletariat’, and the part accessing and controlling the productive capital becomes historically the ‘bourgeoisie’, the class of classical capitalists.

    Thespeculative capital,on the symbolic level, allows a non-working proprietor elite of a population to ‘invest’ in entire productive enterprises and to treat these as abstract ‘goods’ whose profits—typically becoming rents—are objects of conjecture and‘speculation’, that is, moving capital in and out of entire production zones, and countries.Speculative profits are obtained by investments in investments, and are used in many ethically more or less problematic ways, essentially for political manipulation, lobbying,buying rulers or propagandists and feeding secret agencies and mafias; for imperial,expansionist, colonial, energy-related or religious warfare; and for controlling illegal and secretive mega-markets exchanging reference values such as uranium, gold, drugs, art works, jewellery, etc. It is worthy of notice that the activities happening on the symbolic level of capital and power are considered as situated ‘a(chǎn)bove’ ordinary legality; sovereignty is allied with sacredness and is therefore essentially untouchable and not accessible to formal lawmaking and jurisdiction.21Laws mainly exist as immanent regulators of productive and reproductive life, on the second level of social structure. They presuppose a public sphere of discourse, whereas the symbolic transactions transgress this sphere of discourse; they are only displayed if the ‘show’ serves the imaginary construction of beliefs and support (the social dream factory, so to speak). Money buys lives and deaths, and modern ‘lobbying’ is a good model of the alliance of secrecy and display that dominates on this level. It is, in this sense, constitutively transgressive, which is no doubt the most important obstacle to all political or judicial attempts to limit its dangerous effects on societies, but it is no doubt also the most forceful motive for individual and pathological aspirations to power—meaning “total”, and totalitarian, unbridled power beyond moral restrictions. Power in this sense is psychologically sexy to the point of inducing psychopathy and psychosis: madness.22It can be strongly seductive if supported by submissive social communication, and it has demonstrated its appeal to ‘the People’throughout the various, more or less irrational, totalitarian populisms, or despotic populocracies, of world history.

    The most important effect of the introduction of the systems of capital in a social formation is, however, the modern vertical integration of the instances (1), (3) and (5),community, property, and sovereignty, which finally become levels of institutional,hierarchical Nation States.23The Statewas basically and primordially just the reproductive community, but it is now also materialized in property as real estate, the ‘property of the people’, ‘res publica’, an independent, overarching social Subject that can own and manage productive capital. The holder of sovereignty becomes a ruler of this vertical(three-level) State apparatus, paid by generalized taxation and supported by both a currency-controlling ‘national bank’ and, often, a religious establishment.

    The phenomenon of the integrative and ‘national’ State is thus inseparable from the monetarization of the social formation. The smooth trans-capitalistic (three-level)circulation of monetary values and the subsequent material exchanges are what gives rise to the protective (monetary, currency-based) feeling of social oneness we find in nationalisms,paradoxically running in parallel to the still more exacerbated contrasts between the forms of capital—the speculative, the productive, and the organic-reproductive—and the population’s class gaps, an inequality following from these contrasts. Money, State, and‘People’ are interdependent concepts. But markets currently integrate internationally, and financial operations do that particularly fast; markets and speculative movements expand the domination of money so intensely that it tends to dissolve the national, that is, Statebased, legal boundaries in favor of unstable networks of capital streams, a process now referred to by the termglobalization(French:mondialisation). The globalization of money means that nation states can all be indebted to non-national, globally active banking systems connecting the speculative capitals and sovereignties of the world. In this process,money seems to lose all reference to currencies and metals, and to become a purelyfiatentity that can be createdex nihiloby issuing debts, as Graeber (2011) suggests. Money seems to become radically infinite, since nothing limits its continuous creation and the subsequent creation of indebted instances. This historically important process is now reaching the limits of possible substantial growth of production, and its destructive effects on the planet make it clear that numerically infinite economies cannot harmonically coexist with a qualitatively finite and fragile planetary ecology.

    The political consequences of this dilemma are not yet known, but international confusion is increasingly felt, and the human costs of the political unrest caused by the current frenetic behavior of capitalism are already unbearable.

    What we call representative democracy is clearly an effect of the integrated State,where the hierarchical ordering of the levels of stasis can be expressed in terms of formalrepresentationof individuals and groups by other individuals and groups. Since the entire system is constitutively permeated by money, and representative status can be handled as a sort of commodity, the representative principle is, however, essentially unstable. Its monetary origin and ground remain manifest in its instability: mafias, lobbies, totalitarian excesses are never far away from the pockets of democratic ‘representatives’. In this framework, social life will thus contain a political life, which mainly regulates the relative strength of the statal institutions on all levels and the market interests on all levels, as these functions affect reproduction, production, and sovereignty.

    Since political life unfolds in the substance of discourse, the statal side opposes the commercial side as a ‘left wing’ opposes a ‘right wing’ in the discursive public sphere, or as a ‘progressive’ versus a ‘reactionary’ attitude in discourse. We might call this standard variation thehorizontal dynamicsof political discourse. State supporters versus market supporters. There is, however, a different determination of discursive style to consider,namely the vertical dynamics stemming from the superimposed capital forms. The third,symbolic stream generates a ‘wild’, transgressive motive that conceptualizes social power in terms of charisma-baseddespotism, whether autocratic or theocratic, or both. This style contrasts with the conceptualization of social power emanating from the productive capital,which is and must belegalistic. Legislation, based on bureaucracy, is central in political life on the level of the productive capital.24Despotism and legalism form an essential vertical opposition, or variation in style, crossing the horizontal left–right opposition. So just as we find two forms of ‘left-wing’ discourse, one revolutionary (‘hard’ and more or less despotic) and the other reformist (‘soft’ and legalistic), we find in ‘right-wing’ discourse a split between ‘hard’, despotic reactionaries (populist, fascist) and ‘soft’ legalistic conservatives. However, on the basic level of reproductive capital, the discourse is rather of a third type, namelypragmatic. In the perspective of this discourse, on the one hand, even bad solutions are better than bad problems, so in some cases ‘hard’, terroristic anarchism,in other cases ‘softer’ and more democratic anarchism will be preferred, depending on the immediate effect of the remedy.25On the other hand, short-term pragmatism,opportunism, can contrast long-term pragmatism, grass-root ecology, seriously; short-term solutions to the problem of ‘getting rid of’ waste by dumping it in the oceans create longterm problems by eliminating aquatic animal life, an important source of human food.Ecology in the sense of this essay is in fact a form of long-term pragmatism, namely what economists call ‘negative externalities’—the fundamental problem being how to maintain the planet as a human habitat. Capitals, that is, the agents of capitals on all levels, are not inherently organic and not naturally interested in questions of life; money is not a biological species, just a predominant form of human symbolization regulating life and, in the current historical situation, more than ever deregulating it.

    3. Problems

    3.1 The ecological problem

    In the integrated and globalizing capitalistic perspective, coherence can only exist in terms of monetary coherence, which means that the semantics of money must prevail.Themeaning of moneyis to circulate—protectively26—and in order to do so, since circulation however smooth is costly and implies loss, to increase, instead of decrease:growthmust happen. An ideology of necessary growth must develop. But for material growth to happen, the negentropic-entropic loops exploiting natural resources on all levels (organic, technical, symbolic; affecting soils, oceans, atmosphere etc.) must be exploited infinitely, that is, must be handled according to the formal infinity of capitals; and this has led to such destruction, pollution, and exhaustion of habitats and resources that human and animal life on the planet is now becoming seriously threatened. The metaphorical use of the organic termgrowthfor the inanimate, purely symbolic finality of capitals is tragically ironic. Money is not a living organism that can “grow”, as this metaphor has it. The problem is whether it will manage to fully exhaust and destroy its own necessary material foundation, the natural loops that carry it, before it is itself ‘outgrown’ by a healthier principle of human organization, a sustainable form of reproduction, production,and symbolization. We may have to discuss the possibility of ‘sustainable symbolization’and thus, of the sustainability of money as such. What is bound to happen globally is a dramatic matter of time, as ecology always is and locally has been. Can money be separated from capitalism and be cured from its apparently inherent madness? Can some humanethicsfinally make money rational and ecologically viable? Or can human civilization, as we know it, exist without the symbolic medium we call money? The latter question evidently presupposes an understanding of what moneyis, which is the question that motivates our semiotic inquiry.

    3.2 The political problem

    If the “growth” of the generalized and globalized capital is slowed down by the ecological difficulties it has created, and in particular by the impossibility of obtaining the quantities of energy needed for increasing the material production, then an increasing part of the total capital will move ‘upwards’ toward the pure symbolic and speculative level. This is happening now and may account for the current ‘growth’ of diffuse and irrational outbursts of sovereign insanity, including neocolonial warfare, religious militancy, and,no doubt, a very dangerous general turn to religiousandneocolonial belligerence, in many parts of the planet—again, capital must stay active, circulate, flow, move and be used in order to exist. It exists ‘growingly’, andsymbolic hyperactivityof this kind can probably only be stopped by political intervention. But such intervention would mainly or only spring from the basic, pragmatic level, where populations are hit by corresponding misery; and here, the weakened monetary flow reduces them to just asking again for... protection, i.e. more money and insanity. Intellectual political resistance is additionally inhibited by the lack of conceptual distinctions between capital forms, and by the predominant vision oftheCapital,das Kapital, as one tremendous, homogeneous,indivisible, and maybe invincible block, not a stratified system whose strata might be made relatively independent and amenable to regulation. The semio-ecological view may therefore become useful.27

    3.3 The problem of knowledge

    Institutions for the development and the transmission of knowledge are collective Subjects or persons that are in the hands of either the State or the Market, and often in both sorts of hands. These share the fate of the ‘public sphere’ of information, debate, critical discourse, entertainment, advertisement, and propaganda – namely to be a plaything between States and an integrated, overarching Market. Human minds naturally strive for insights and accurate knowledge of the world, and at least what we callscience, history,and philosophy, three main branches of real systematic and critical search for knowledge,are essentially the developed collaborative versions of this natural human drive.However, knowledge and its ‘truths’—however approximate—can be disturbing, and morally challenged persons can be persuaded monetarily to hide, deny, and distort such disturbance. As organic, technical, and symbolic knowledge is becoming increasingly important to the survival of human beings in the current dangerous physical and organic state of the planet, these counter-epistemic inhibiting factors are becoming particularly problematic. Thetechnologies of epistemic and counter-epistemic agency, the industries of information and delusion, including the media of the ‘public sphere’ and of the new‘private sphere’ of more intimate personal digital media, make the task of politically building on real knowledge, rather than on interested misinformation, extremely difficult. As Plato already observed, truth should not be a commodity that you can buy (as you can buy and take a course in rhetoric with Gorgias). Neither truths nor money are ordinary commodities; they are ‘sovereign’ symbolic entities. But money can therefore oppose truth, and knowledge is often ‘taken hostage’, ‘bought’: privatized, patented as property,made inaccessible and useless. However, truths are the necessary weapons of an ethical regulation of money-based power, because truth is a supreme form of authority that power must itself appear to possess. Why else would it have a tendency to lie?

    3.4 The problem of culture

    The frequently occurring direct fusion of sovereignty (5) and religion (6) in a conjuncture of inflated financial-speculative capitalism creates a particularly dangerous and explosive situation in a technically fragilized world-system of societies.28Religions merging with sovereignty potentially create a dangerous caste of priest-warrior-bankers-rulers on top of weakened political States. In such conjunctures, ethnic passions will replace rationality and inhibit, censure or exclude deliberative discourse, and the local and global results will be utterly destructive. By contrast, when ethno-cultural particularities are maintained and only transmitted on the basic organic level of households, their pretentions are limited, and they mainly assure elementary reproductive functions in family lives:ritualized burials, marriages, baptisms, celebration of events in the mythical calendar.However, these cultural functions ofcult(in the instances 1 and 2 of fig. 3, above) are easily subsumed by the religious-financial elites (6), which can then mobilize the organic masses, already distressed and disoriented by the destructive effects of speculative capitals, and manipulate these to follow irrational orders and interests of inflated religious rulers (5-6).

    4. (Im)possible Alternatives

    Contemporary philosophers frequently argue against the current structural reign of money,which now causes these spectacular disasters; but most often they argue without indicating realistic means of changing the situation. Certain forms of hope are indeed expressed. So, economists hope that more and new, hitherto unseen forms of ‘growth’ will eventually ease the situation and repair the damage caused by capital-driven violence and destruction.Such expectations of course do not include the devastation of nature; for economy is not ecology. On the other hand, revolutionary mysticisms thrive, among mundane philosophers and intellectuals hoping that the global proletariat will somehow again climb the mythical barricades; and yet the elementary question remains: what to do about the monetary or otherwise symbolic condition, even after a new revolution, global or local. The question concerns all inhabitable areas of the planet—will mankind be able to reorganize and develop a high-technological global social formation without its ‘wild’ speculative money? Or would we have to scale down to tribal society formats and try to make that work? Or again:can money stay with us but without capitalism? This sounds like a rhetorical question. But it may become a realistic and even an urgent problem to solve.

    Certain anti-capitalistic views would see the solution in a new strengthening of the State, making it possible to fight the strong integration and hegemony of the markets. But as we are seeing already, States and markets can be strengthened at the same time; we could reanimate or generalize one of history’s particularly unfortunate anti-capitalistic models, but global ecology is not likely to be served.

    Neo-liberal thinkers are convinced that new technologies of some kind will overcome the hurdles of growth; they hope that increases of energy consumption will therefore not be necessary. Production is supposed to grow but the energy flow will proportionally shrink or stay on current levels. The new technology will not need increased extraction, just immaterial smartness. But smartness alone is not relevant production in any sense before it producesmorethan is presently the case, which again requires increased extraction and energy and material consumption, and if growth is just stagnation with lowered costs due to smart robots, the production and maintenance of these new machines will again require increased extraction and consumption. A growth with zero-increase in energy consumption and waste is simply impossible. Believing otherwise amounts to relying on miracles.

    Money has created the human historical world as we know it. And money is now about to destroy it. Still nothing is in view that could replace it without itself being money(e.g. bitcoin29). The remaining question is therefore the deepest and simplest: Can money be changed into something less pervasive and destructive?30Or is there another semiotic way to organize an intelligent post-capitalistic society?

    The answer may depend on the interpretation of the underlying flows and the social stases that these flows must create for human populations to live.31Maybe new attention should be paid to the sacred origin of money32as an atavistic means of contact with the divine. It should be clear that reducing the capitalistic size and importance of this instance((6) in the model) and its alliances with political rulers ((5) in the model) could reduce the toxic effects, initiatives, and attitudes that flow from this sphere and that inhibit human political thinking: intolerance, arrogance, fanaticism—irrationalisms of all kinds.No viable solution can be worked out under the dominance of violence, corruption,and financially militarized religion. If the symbolic flow of financio-religio-despoticospeculative capital can be reduced and weakened,state rulers may gain rationality,which is a prerequisite for gaining control of the lawless forces at work on this third level. The goal would be a significant reduction of the role of ‘wild money’ in the global circulation, that is, a certain ‘de-capitalization’ of the third level, and a corresponding ‘rerationalization’ of governance.

    Instead of yielding to despair faced with the global capitalization of money, it may be possible to dwell on its substantial layering, which subsists despite all types of State and Market integration, combination, and conflict. It may be important to remember that the role of money is stilldifferentfrom one ecological level to another, and that the danger to mankind of activity being determined mainly by monetary flows increases drastically from level to level upwards, and decreases in the opposite direction. Money needs to be taken ‘down’ from speculative dominance. The fatal lack of rationality occurs mainly at the highest level; therefore, initiatives to limit the severe ecological and human damages caused by the functions of capital in our contemporary societies should primarily target the symbolic top of the monetary flows and their influential bodies of power, the ties between speculative wealth, politico-economic ruling power and religious mind control.The theme of growth may be crucial here: it needs to be deeply problematized.

    Since the Axial Age, through Antiquity, the feudal Middle Ages, the commercial Renaissance, the agonistic Baroque, Industrial Romanticism, and technological Modernism, money has given rise to many great and impressive social and cultural developments and achievements worldwide, however often obtained to a saddening price paid by nature and life. Currently, the planetary situation calls for a profound rational reconsideration of the monetary world order, and we must find ways to empower forms of political rationality capable of changing the perspective, and in particular, to reduce the irrational agency caused by the monetary world orderas it is.

    If I am right, the symbolic flow, which is the main historical cause of the disaster,has an interesting weak spot, namely that it is and remains—symbolic. It is semiotically symbolic and refers to itself; this is the root of all irrationalism, but also of rationalism:‘meta-language’, self-reference. Symbolicity is necessarily driven bylanguage, which is easily used self-referentially. And money has often been compared to language.33It is strikingly true that language, in the shape ofdiscourse—in fact a rich display of differentdiscourses, political, religious, ideological, etc., each with its own aesthetical norms of well-formedness and rhetorical forms, which constitute the delight of semiotic analysis34—pervades social and cultural formations as much as, and even more than money. Money itself would not exist without language to negotiate, define, and compare the properties of pieces or quantities of monetary value. But furthermore, religious practices as well as political acts are entirely shaped by language—their operations and terms depend on the intelligibility and thecredibilityof political and religious discourse, and of their combinations. That is why social rulers and religious authorities must spectacularlydisplaytheir agency in constant massive and, of course, ostentatiously costly, lavish and wasteful theatrical setups. If an equally massive or socially audible rational critique of these displays, and their inherently vacuous futility and essentially stultifying simulacra,could obtain sufficient material support to become a real challenge, despite all technical attempts to silence it, then therolesof money may in fact be changed, and the fate of mankind made to look less sombre.

    An explicit critique of transgressive sovereignty—what sort of discourse could materialize its task?Wherewould it speak from, as Michel Foucault (1971) would ask. While symbolic capital and activities in general are inherently aggressive and transgressive, the authority of the law is inoperative on this transcendent level, often technically powerless, as demonstrated every day in contemporary social and political life. Still, language has an advantage, and even sacred versions of sovereignty have a weak spot where this advantage is located: language and only language can make it exist socially, and language comes with a built-inethics of enunciation: to speak is to care for others, to give voice to an elementary ethical claim of respect for life and therefore for truth. Evil is inherently silent or nonsensical. Anethical critique of sovereignty,formulated in the prosaic or poetical language of organic human experience and subsequently in the discourse of a philosophy of responsibility, may be a means to obtain the necessary change of mind. All humans capable of following a story and grasping its narrative logic in principle do understand the distinction between serving life and serving death, between helping and harming, and between responsible reason and irresponsible madness. The semantics of a fundamentally ethical claim in fact should have a chance to at least transcend ethnic passions and powerful pathological behaviors. Lawyers of the current academic sort will probably reject it, but beyond the unavoidable formalisms of laws, there is anethical conditionfor human life to make sense, namely the call toprotect the other, not as money was supposed to do according to its semantic ‘value’, justprotect yourself. This grounding ethical call to protect others around you (the individual you),including those of the still more precarious future, is a strong call deeply rooted in human nature, and it is, I think, strong enough to fight and defeat the speculative madness of money, when the ecological catastrophes accumulate.35As idle capitals accumulate, so do these catastrophes, by direct proportionality—and there will be a tipping point where the discourse of ethical ecology becomes the only voice capable of countering radical pessimism. It would however be cynical to passively await such a moment.

    The monetary sign is performative, that is, it has the same performative force as the utterance of a declaration, a promise, a threat. It is a materialized promise. Either the money is given by A to B or not; either the promise by A addressing B is made or not. If given, made, a situation has changed. But money can only be given and received within a frame of specified exchange that must be defined by language. This exchange is an act of ‘buying’, of ‘lending’, of ‘donating’, or of ‘bribing’, etc. Language is therefore conceptually superimposed on money. This is interesting, because in the last instance,and especially when used for illicit, transgressive purposes, as shown in crime fiction and corresponding reality, language must follow an inherent principle ofdiscursive ethicsthat forces the user todo as promised(in casu, keep a secret, tell the same lie as someone else, etc.), that is, to be linguistically reliable. If this principle is not respected, the subject is excluded even from a criminal community. Only psychosis or brain damage can make the speaker deviate from this fundamental principle of ethics of language use. Ethics in this sense is stronger than morality and law, and therefore it can bewhere to speak fromin a future critique of destructive capitals. Laws can be bent, ignored, interpreted in many fanciful ways; but the ethics of language use, which is the grounding ethics of the human being as such, cannot. This source, the grounding human ethics of meaning and truth, is from where art, literature, music come, and from where responsible scholars, scientists, and philosophers speak and write, if they have the personal capacity and integrity to assume their task, which admittedly is not always the case. In particular, one may quite often suspect academic economists to neglect to display such conceptual and ethical integrity.

    Money may be pervasive, but it is ruled by language. It may therefore be politically and structurally changeable by language, art, music, emotional expressions of commitments to life, in the name of the very ethics that makes us human. We may have to find our wayintothis critical core of our communicative being if we want to find our wayoutof the current maze of despotic or erratic capitalism, mental confusion and ecological disaster.

    5. The Realms of Meaning

    In Georges Bataille’s so-called heterology, which describes experiences and observations of behaviors corresponding to what is happening on the symbolic level in my analysis of societal structure, power and madness are linked to excess, transgression of rationality and of norms, behaviors of ‘sovereignty’ both in a collective and in the individual scale.His social phenomenology is indifferent to such scale shifts between the macro-social and the micro-social or even intimate realms. It strikes me that this conceptual plasticity calls for justification, and that we might now have an explanatory argument at hand.

    The three levels of societal organization, including their interactions and interdependent processes, with or without the intervention of money, are matched by three levels of semantic organization that we find inall human semiotic phenomena of meaning-making:in language, art, music, affectivity, normativity. We will briefly consider this subjective perspective and its consequences.

    5.1 Levels of meaning in socio-cultural life

    The terminology proposed by psychoanalyst Jacques Lacan36to characterize the main instances active in the human mind:the Symbolic, the Imaginary, the Real, can be transposed to describe the levels of meaning in socio-cultural life:

    III. TheSymboliclevel of meaning: authority and ritual force; ‘identity’ and violence;POWER.

    II. TheImaginarylevel of meaning: social representations and projects of all kinds; WORK.

    I. TheReallevel of meaning: family, friendship, love, births, deaths. Existential aspects; LIFE.

    We experience social life first by growing up in a collective setting, by being and taking part in its daily endeavors. Our existentialrealityconsists of passionate bindings to others and learning to follow their rules and norms, their ‘moral’ principles. But we soon learn that there are larger social horizons regulated by laws issued by institutions and addressing us as citizens, as principles of ‘legality’ to follow (or fight). We encounter this sort of meaning as an encyclopedic mass ofimaginaryentities: projects, political ‘dreams’and ideologies, references to knowledge, myths, stories, information, propaganda, etc.Finally, we discover that there are ‘higher’ orders of decision making, transcendent principles of authority, sacredness, andsymbolicacts without rational explanations, which seems to venerate some sort of shared destiny that calls upon our participation. The latter‘order’ is no longer regulated by the civil and ordinarylaw, nor by themoralnorms of the basic, real level, but either by the sovereign madness of sacralized rulers or else by some superordinate principles of universalethics—such as what we call the Human Rights and an ethics of care for nature: ecology.

    5.2 Language and subjectivity

    A division in the registers of meaning characteristic of language is straight forward and appears natural. In the register of speech acts, the presupposed authority of the speaker and the relevance of the hearer makes it possible to create new interpersonal and social situations by declaring, promising, imperatives, curses, conjurations, oaths, and other performative utterances in the present tense. This is the symbolic semantics of language.But in the framework of the non-performative functions of language, communication simultaneously builds universes ofimaginarypolitical, educational, esthetic, narrative meaning allowing human societies to operate as huge networks of connected and collaborative (incl. polemically responsive) minds. The open-class words that constantly change their meaning and reference, migrate between languages, and follow the historical and technical developments of cultures and countries, form the necessary grounds of all social life. Finally, the phenomenological,realregister in language is dominated by proper names, place names, pet names, nicknames, markers of singular (numerical) identities that are essential in our affective and intimate life; idiomatisms, dialects, sociolects, and sexolects may therefore pertain to the same register.

    In the domain of the personal pronouns,you (singular) and Iare anchored in the basic, real, phenomenological register, whereaswe and you (plural)mark the collective imaginary, and thewe (singular),as in “we, the king”, refers to the symbolic instance.

    In these respects, language is shaped by deep ecological structuration of human sociality. It can be argued thatsignsin general, not only linguistic signs, but visual,auditive, gestural, or otherwise humanly configured expressions, including artistic expression, which are often complex integrations of expressions of various modalities, manifest a similarly differentiated semantic unfolding. One part of a sign always signifies an instruction: thesymbolicaspect; another part always to some extent indicates what something referred to is like: theiconicaspect; and one part of the sign connotes its context or origin and value to the speaker, therealaspect, in Lacan’s sense.

    One of the most important categories of subjectivity is of course affect. Human affectivity divides in several independent but interrelated systems, including regulators of our mental and bodily state in different time scales. The ‘fastest’ affects are the shiftingemotionsby which we experience our constantly changing social situations: joy, surprise, anger, fear, sadness, concern, sorrow, shame, pride, contempt, disgust... The time scale refers to minutes of expression and feeling. This category corresponds directly to our insertion in the socialimaginary.

    The category of what we callmoodscover the somewhat ‘slower’ affective states of excitement, elation, ecstacy, and their opposites: depression, dejection, melancholy. Between these polar extremes, there is a neutral state; the time scale for being in the nonneutral states of mood is the day, because they are regulated by our circadian rhythms,and because thesymbolic calendarand our ritual behavioral routines let our binding to the symbolic instances determine the choice of state, at least to a certain extent. Religion is therefore a regulator of mood, and one that easily binds our subjectivity to sacredness and authority.

    Finally, the sort of affect we call passions relates to our existential feelings: being-inlove, love (itself), grief, affection, bitterness, resentment, hatred... Those states of mind and body are ‘long-term’ affects. Their scale is the year; they regulate and often dramatize our real existential life.

    5.3 The architecture of the human mind is identical to that of society. Madness

    It is thus a reasonable assumption that the three levels of social flow are imprinted in the human minds and bodies, that is, that they have been shaping our subjectivity during the many—maybe at least ten—millenia in which we have been living in social formations articulated in this way. This would explain that social events immediately affect us individually; from gossip to news programs and media messages, what ‘happens’around us directly determine our personal thoughts and feelings to a striking degree:the individual experiences society as a part of itself. So social ‘crises’ often become individual crises as well. And madness in one sense becomes madness in another sense:social rulers experience their body as a country; psychotic conditions can induce similar feelings, for example the feeling of being a ruler because the body has become a country. Psychology and sociology coincide as to their orders, levels, and semiotic processes—the human mind is a radically social machine, one may say.

    If this is correct, at least as a first approximation, we may begin to understand how money can enter the human mind with such a tremendous imperative force, as the semiotic entity that the individual feels it must relate to. Money can enter the mind exactly as language does and by following the very example of language (given that language must have preceded it in the human symbolic evolution). Money becomes an irresistiblemaster signin the flows of our affectivity, and quasi-automatically regulates our reasoning, giving rise to the so-calledeconomical rationalitythat critical theories have problematized. However, we do not need any theory of authoritarian personalities in order to grasp the endemic logic of monetary submission in modern human psychology.We do not even need theories of ‘reflection’ by which the mind mirrors social processes;our mindsarethese processes. What we instead do need in order to fight and limit the madness of money in our real, political, and symbolic lives is an understanding of the genealogy and general semiotic economy of money and the underlying ecology. In the finiteness of our ecology is the remedy for the delirious infinity of our economical imagination.

    Villeneuve-sur-Yonne, June 2017

    Notes

    1 Walt Disney’s, that is, Carl Barks’, philosophical and pedagogical masterpiece, the cartoon Donald Duck, has a character, Scrooge McDuck, who owns a money tank filled with gold coins; it serves as his swimming pool and allows him to physically enjoy his immense wealth by bodily contact with the liquid of his ‘money’.

    2 To ‘give someone your word’, in the sense of making a promise, has the same effect of irreversibly depositing an entity of value. You ‘pawn’ your language and must ‘pay’ (fulfil the promise) to get it back.

    3 Critical semiotic approaches are taken by social philosophers such as Jean Baudrillard (1972)or Ferruccio Rossi-Landi (1974). The assumption of these attempts is that linguistic and monetary signs essentially work the same way. Words are the money of our bodies. Both are conventional, and both have performative force. We will return to this analogistic view, which calls for serious modification, a modification that can profit from a closer study of monetary functions.

    I should specify that I am talking about standard neoclassical economics. I admit that several heterodox economists, and the school called Modern Money Theory (MMT), or Chartalism, do place monetary institutions at the center of macroeconomics. A main distinction is made between metal money and paper money, the latter seen as being created by states through declarative acts (therefore nicely called:fiatmoney). The first modern theoretist of money, Ferdinando Galliani, whoseDella moneta, inspired by Hume, appeared in 1751, was a‘state metallist’: he suggested that metal money emerged spontaneously out of states’ need for a manageable tax-paying reference.

    4 Georges Bataille (1944). The negentropic loop referred to here also underlies Bataille’s (1947)concept of a ‘general economy’, which opposes the restricted economy of production, profit,and reinvestment, by including the instances of destruction of wealth, as in wars or costly displays, typically related to the symbolization of sovereignty.

    5 I will argue that money arises from symbolic activity in this sense. The contemporary ‘Modern Money Theory’ economist L. Randall Wray, a student of the fiat-money pioneer Hyman Minsky, supports the view that all these psychological and symbolic aspects of collective life are involved in capital formation (Wray, 1990). He opposes the standard and Marxian view that money emerges from exchange of goods. Whereas the exchange-based view imagines that money as such develops bottom-up, so to speak, i.e. from barter, he reaches a conclusion similar to that of the present author, namely that it originates in a top-down process, from the symbolic level.

    6 This statement sounds like an ideological standard phrase. But understanding the origin of‘private’ (person-assigned) property is not a problem solved by Morgan, Marx, Engels or any other modern social scientist. Here, we will bluntly assume that the concept of real property evolves out of ownership applied to objects and entities on the level of the technical flow. How‘private’ it eventually becomes, or again ceases to be, is a historical question. Friedrich Engels’(1884 – 1892) work on the subject,The Origin of the Family, Private Property, and the State,remains a major contribution to the discussion.

    7 In ancient cultures, temples often also served as banks. The biblical Jesus caused scandal by expelling the bankers from the temple of Jerusalem, thus marking the modern distinction—which remains relative. The original unity is recalled by institutions like the most CatholicBanco del Santo Spirito.

    8 For there to be a population, there has to be a territory inhabited by people sharing language,moral and technical habits, history, and interpreting that territory in terms of its life forms.

    9 Graeber, 2011. The original German term isAchsenzeit, the period from about 8th to 3rd century BC, suggested by the philosopher Karl Jaspers (1949) to be a decisive founding phase of the great civilizations that would follow in many areas of the planet simultaneously.In Mesopotamia, gold ornaments first appeared in the fifth millenium BC. Gold played a prominent part in funeral gifts and ceremonial objects. Cult statues was often covered with gold foil. In the mid-second millenium, gold from Egypt was imported in exchange from the pharaoh by the Babylonian kings in exchange for richly worked textiles, war chariots, etc.

    10 Brandt, 2015a, 2015b.

    11 Remember that, e.g., the etymologically important JunoMonetawas a powerful protective Roman goddess. The imputed inherent protective force of money therefore grounds its semantics of abstract ‘value’.

    12 Money thus also exists as a store of value. In contrast toSay’s law,as J. M. Keynes critically named this well-known belief that money is just a momentary link between two acts of buying,and that the market is thus self-regulating, we in fact hoard money as a bulwark against uncertainty. Jean-Baptiste Say formulated the principle in hisTraité d’Economie politique,1803. “Money performs but a momentary function in this double exchange; and when the transaction is finally closed, it will always be found, that one kind of commodity has been exchanged for another.”

    13 Of course, the affective background of the semantics of money, on this account, is the omnipresence of the universal basic emotionfear. Money is experienced as a remedy against this feeling. Through the three millennia of the history of money, this circumstance has stayed stable. Money is still experienced as protective. This is true even when it is used as female adornment, for example. Or in wedding rings, protecting the contract. And it is characteristic of sacred imagery to still use precious metal adornment abundantly, as if to constantly remind us of its origin.

    14 Schmandt-Besserat, 1996.

    15 The wordcapitalis derived from the same Latin root as cattle:caput, “head” (of cattle).

    16 Religion and sovereign money seem to cooperate across cultures and through history. On the websiteNew Economic Perspectives, L. Randall Wray critically quotes Nobel Prize winner Paul Samuelson’s remark, that “[...] one of the functions of old fashionedreligionwas to scare people by sometimes what might be regarded as myths into behaving in a way that the longruncivilized liferequires. We have taken away a belief in the intrinsic necessity of balancing the budget if not in every year, [then] in every short period of time. [...]” Wray does not believe in the religion of balancing state budgets for the mythical reason that ‘one must always pay what one owes’. He writes: “We don’t need myths. We need more democracy, more understanding, and more transparency. We do need to constrain our leaders—but not through dysfunctional superstitions.”

    17 Hyman Minsky, one of the founders of MMT, distinguished three forms: commercial, welfare state, and money manager capitalism, fairly comparable to our three strata of capitalin general. Minsky (1986) noticed that a surplus of productive capitalimmediatelyspills over into speculative capital, which destabilizes the ‘system’.

    18 Commodity money (coins) was first replaced by representative money (paper) in China,according to Marco Polo, and became then “represented” by bank notes in the 17th century in Europe. Paper money remains anchored in references to gold or silver until the second part of the 20th century, when the references seem to become autonomous: the pieces of paper finally inherit the protective magic of the metals, if properly authenticated. Paper money consists in documents stating debts to the person owning the documents. The debt statement is a performative act, adeclaration of a promise, signed by the issuer of the unique and singular piece of paper to whoever will own it.

    Commodity money represents value as a link between nominal units of currency and quantity of coined metal. A very interesting debate involving the philosopher John Locke took place in the last decade of the English 18th century, around the Great Recoinage 1696-1700;guided by the philosopher, the run-down shilling was recoined with as much silver as there had been a century before, and it was decided to keep the rate fixed. Soon, the pound was bound to fixed amounts of gold in the same way, by the Bank of England. See John Locke, “Further Considerations Concerning Raising the Value of Money”, in Kelly, 1991.

    19 Theoikosis of course a house, a home, but it does not yet really count as a value, contrarily to what is the case on the technical level, where it becomes a priced Property. Mostly, either the dwelling is built by the owner or it is rented. On the other hand, the termecology—introduced by the German biologist and philosopher Ernst Haeckel in 1866—refers to the sameoikos,now in the sense of “niche”, and tologosin the sense of study: the biological or social study of the interactions between organisms and their environments.

    20 Banks define the difference between capitalists and proletarians: the former can borrow money, because the can offer mortgage, the latter cannot, since their ‘property’ is considered null.

    21 That sovereign governments can create money ‘out of thin air’ still scares modern citizens.

    22 Sergio Tonkonoff (2012) offers a fine and finely written account of Bataille’s view of human transgression. Sovereignty in this dramatic sense can be seen as a paradoxically permanent ‘state of emergency’, as in the Italian philosopher Giorgio Agamben’s thinking, inspired by Carl Schmitt. See Agamben 1995. He understandably wishes to get rid of it altogether; I doubt the possibility of building a society without a symbolic level. But since thelawthat regulates the conflicts on the second level does not have much effect on the third level, we might instead look at transcendent principles such as the Human Rights to find the ethical principles that can limit the irrationality of this third, dangerously destructive level of sociality.

    23 This conception is not far from the Chartalist view of the multiple functions of money (see

    note 3).

    24 We rediscover in this context Karl Jaspers’ friend Max Weber’s (1905) famous opposition of charismatic and bureaucratic power, both superseding the power of traditions and conventions,which are of course rooted in the necessities of reproductive life. In my view, Weber’s categories are essentially superimposed on each other, rather than historically sequenced.

    25 We could call this style of management acowboy logic. The hero of such conflicts and stories is typically a pragmatician, which can be felt as a relief from the stressing higher-order conflict between the four predominant styles described here.

    26 The meaning of money is to yield protection, if my analysis is correct. The fundamental concept of ‘value’ in economics is based on this semantic effect. Some heterodox economists, from Keynes and Minsky to Wray, may agree, whereas neo-classical mainstream economists just consider money as a neutral, insignificant element of macroeconomics.

    27 There is certainly a dynamic Agonist-Antagonist relation between productive and speculative instances, and wild speculation stemming from stases 3 and 4 profits can be ruled in and stabilized by stasis 5. There is a feedback loop from stasis 5 to stasis 1: ‘financial reason’, in a sense.

    28 I insist that there is nothing new in this alliance between sovereignty and religion. Its basic expression is the very existence of money, created at least 3,000 years ago. Still, stasis 5 and 6 can be kept distinct, as in ‘secular’ regimes. Ethno-religious passions frequently disturb this distinctive condition.

    29 My colleague Todd Oakley comments that bitcoin is not money, unless you can pay taxes with it. An open theoretical question; I think he is right, in the sense that to be money is to be able to connect the levels of capital in integrated flows.

    30 My reviewer, who evidently is a heterodox economist, comments nicely on the question: “It depends on the institutions around it. The power of sovereign currency systems to fulfill a public purpose that stabilizes societies is indeed possible, at least for a time, but pathological fears of insolvency (not possible for sovereign currencies) and inflation (not on the horizon) is a great hurdle to overcome. It also means embracing the transgressive prerogatives of the state(which can be used to fulfill the public purpose just as much as to aggrandize the sovereign).”

    31 Modern Monetary Theory takes the view that the Sovereign or Government sector must run deficits most if not all of the time, as public debt in a sovereign currency is not only a debt in the nominal sense; more importantly, it is mostly savings of the private sector).

    32 Weber already pointed out the close connection between economy and religion, but in a different key, namely as a relation between moral standards of Protestantism, especially Calvinism, and the norms of industrial capitalism.

    33 See Rossi-Landi, 1975; Baudrillard, 1972 ; Bataille, 1949. The Swiss linguist Ferdinand de Saussure famously says ([1915] 1962), in Chapter IV of hisCours de linguistique générale,where he discusses what he callsvalueas opposed tosignification, in language : “To determine what a five-franc piece is worth one must therefore know: (1) that it can be exchanged for a fixed quantity of a different thing, e.g. bread; and (2) that it can be compared with a similar value of the same system, e.g. a one-franc piece, or with coins of another system (a dollar,etc.). In the same way, a word can be exchanged for something dissimilar, an idea; besides, it can be compared with something of the same nature, another word. Its value is therefore not fixed so long as one simply states that it can be ‘exchanged’ for a given concept, i.e. that it has this or that signification: one must also compare it with similar values, with other words that stand in opposition to it. Its content is really fixed only by the concurrence of everything that exists outside it. Being part of a system, it is endowed not only with a signification but also and especially with a value, and this is something quite different.” (Translation by Wade Baskin, Internet Archive). The question is whether signification and value can be separated totally. In the case of money, the quantitative value of coins is dependent on their being carriers of protective force; in the case of words, their interdependent ‘value’ depends on their significance as carriers of meaning that can support the communication of truths. If the ‘true’understanding of things protect us from dangers, we have here an analogous function of money and language in terms of signification.

    34 Fontanille, 1998.

    35 As the French ecologist Nicolas Hulot writes on the web page of his association: “In 2050, two hundred fifty millions of people will be forced to leave their habitat by extreme meteorological events (cyclones, typhoons, floods…). The rising waters may swallow between ten thousand and twenty thousand islands, many of them inhabited. One out of six animal species may definitively disappear…”.

    36 See Jacques Lacan (1966, 1975), and passim. Lacan proposed to see the three orders as intertwined as by a borromean knot of three rings, each of which hold together the two others.Lacan is a difficult read, compared to Freud, but his three orders, developed in the discussion around the structuralist turn of psychoanalysis and the humanities in the sixties, may be one of his lasting contributions to social psychology.

    Agamben, G. (1995).Homo sacer. Il poetere sovrano e la nuda vita. Torino: Einaudi.

    Bataille, G. (1944).Le coupable(In?uvres Complètes, Vol. 5). Paris: Gallimard.

    Bataille, G. (1949).La part maudite(In?uvres Complètes, Vol. 7). Paris: Gallimard.

    Baudrillard, J. (1972).Pour une critique de l’économie politique du signe. Paris: Gallimard.

    Brandt, P. A. (2015a). La construction sémio-cognitive de la valeur économique. In A. Biglari(Ed.),Valeurs. Aux fondements de la sémiotique(pp. 481-493). Paris: L’Harmattan.

    Brandt, P. A. (2015b). On the origin and ontology of money. A brief note. Retrieved from https://www.researchgate.net/publication/276970689_On_the_Origin_and_Ontology_of_Money_A_brief_Note

    Fontanille, J. (1998).Sémiotique du discours. Limoges: Presses Universitaires de Limoges.

    Foucault, M. (1971).L’ordre du discours. Le?on inaugurale au Collège de France prononcée le 2 décembre 1970. Paris: Gallimard.

    Graeber, D. (2011).Debt: The first 5,000 years. New York: Melville House.

    Jaspers, K. (1949).Vom Ursprung und Ziel derGeschichte [The origin and goal of History]. München:Piper.

    Kelly, P. H. (Ed.). (1991).Locke on money. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Keynes, J. M. (1919).The economic consequences of the peace. New York: Harcourt, Brace, and Howe.

    Lacan, J. (1966).écrits. Paris: éditions du Seuil.

    Lacan, J. (1975).Encore(1972-1973). Livre XX du Séminaire(Texte établi par Jacques-Alain Miller). Paris: éditions du Seuil.

    Minsky, H. (1986).Stabilizing an unstable economy.New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Monsaingeon, B. (2017).Homo detritus. Critique de la société du déchet.Paris: Le Seuil.

    Rossi-Landi, F. (1975).Linguistics and economics. The Hague: Mouton.

    Schmandt-Besserat, D. (1996).How writing came about.Austin, Texas: University of Texas Press.

    Saussure, F. de. (1962).Cours de linguistique générale(5th ed.). Paris: Payot.

    Tonkonoff, S. (2012). Homo Violens. El Criminal Monstruoso según Georges Bataille.Gramma,13(49.1), 145-152.

    Weber, M. ([1905] 2016).Die protestantische Ethik und der Geist des Kapitalismus.Berlin:Holzinger.

    Wray, L. R. (1990).Money and credit in capitalist economies: The endogenous money approach.Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

    About the author

    Per Aage Brandt (pab18@me.com) is Adjunct Professor at the Department of Cognitive Science of Case Western Reserve University, USA. He studied with Greimas in Paris(Sorbonne Thesis 1987) and was the founder of the Center for Semiotics (1993) at the University of Aarhus, Denmark, and of the JournalCognitive Semiotics(2007). He was a Fellow of the Centre for Advanced Study of the Behavioral Sciences at Stanford, CA.And he is also a poet and a musician.

    中国美白少妇内射xxxbb| 黄色配什么色好看| 国产私拍福利视频在线观看| 国产精品1区2区在线观看.| 婷婷色av中文字幕| 欧美成人a在线观看| 淫秽高清视频在线观看| ponron亚洲| 国产久久久一区二区三区| 精品久久久久久久末码| 国产精品一区二区三区四区久久| 亚洲国产精品合色在线| 一本久久中文字幕| 久久久成人免费电影| 亚洲欧美精品专区久久| 欧美日本视频| 中文在线观看免费www的网站| 久久久久久大精品| 日韩国内少妇激情av| 色吧在线观看| 中文字幕av成人在线电影| 伊人久久精品亚洲午夜| 久久久久久久久久久免费av| 91久久精品国产一区二区成人| 你懂的网址亚洲精品在线观看 | 国产男人的电影天堂91| 亚洲真实伦在线观看| 少妇熟女aⅴ在线视频| 国产久久久一区二区三区| 亚洲国产色片| 国产真实乱freesex| 成人午夜高清在线视频| 我的女老师完整版在线观看| 菩萨蛮人人尽说江南好唐韦庄 | 美女大奶头视频| 天堂中文最新版在线下载 | 国产单亲对白刺激| 熟女人妻精品中文字幕| 男人和女人高潮做爰伦理| 毛片一级片免费看久久久久| 日本免费a在线| 乱人视频在线观看| 黑人高潮一二区| 欧美日本亚洲视频在线播放| 日韩欧美在线乱码| 午夜福利在线观看吧| 99国产极品粉嫩在线观看| 久久久a久久爽久久v久久| 亚洲av一区综合| 亚洲va在线va天堂va国产| 亚洲电影在线观看av| 夜夜夜夜夜久久久久| 美女国产视频在线观看| 看免费成人av毛片| 精品99又大又爽又粗少妇毛片| 一个人观看的视频www高清免费观看| 亚洲人成网站在线播放欧美日韩| 久久欧美精品欧美久久欧美| 国产久久久一区二区三区| 精品久久久久久久久av| 久久久久国产网址| 久久精品国产99精品国产亚洲性色| 国产精品久久久久久久久免| 91久久精品国产一区二区成人| 国内精品久久久久精免费| 在线播放国产精品三级| 高清在线视频一区二区三区 | 成人性生交大片免费视频hd| 我要搜黄色片| av又黄又爽大尺度在线免费看 | 精品久久久久久久人妻蜜臀av| 精品日产1卡2卡| 国产麻豆成人av免费视频| 亚洲婷婷狠狠爱综合网| 最近视频中文字幕2019在线8| 深夜精品福利| 色噜噜av男人的天堂激情| 又粗又爽又猛毛片免费看| 成人特级黄色片久久久久久久| av在线亚洲专区| 国产探花在线观看一区二区| 蜜桃久久精品国产亚洲av| 夜夜夜夜夜久久久久| 国产精品一区www在线观看| 国产精品久久久久久av不卡| 偷拍熟女少妇极品色| 亚洲内射少妇av| 一本—道久久a久久精品蜜桃钙片 精品乱码久久久久久99久播 | 国产日韩欧美在线精品| 老司机福利观看| 国产精品一区二区三区四区久久| 天天躁夜夜躁狠狠久久av| 深夜精品福利| .国产精品久久| 欧美人与善性xxx| 97超碰精品成人国产| 不卡视频在线观看欧美| 精品不卡国产一区二区三区| 悠悠久久av| 国产三级在线视频| 欧美bdsm另类| 26uuu在线亚洲综合色| 欧美+亚洲+日韩+国产| 99国产极品粉嫩在线观看| 免费观看在线日韩| 亚洲欧美日韩东京热| 看十八女毛片水多多多| 亚洲电影在线观看av| 又粗又爽又猛毛片免费看| 亚洲乱码一区二区免费版| 日韩精品有码人妻一区| 日韩欧美三级三区| 精品久久国产蜜桃| 天堂√8在线中文| 中文精品一卡2卡3卡4更新| 亚州av有码| 亚洲精品国产成人久久av| 99久久无色码亚洲精品果冻| 亚洲欧美中文字幕日韩二区| 亚洲成a人片在线一区二区| 晚上一个人看的免费电影| 乱码一卡2卡4卡精品| 国产精品野战在线观看| 国产成人一区二区在线| 国产高清三级在线| 可以在线观看的亚洲视频| 国产精品嫩草影院av在线观看| 一本久久中文字幕| 午夜老司机福利剧场| 老司机影院成人| 男插女下体视频免费在线播放| 好男人在线观看高清免费视频| 国产精品美女特级片免费视频播放器| 国产v大片淫在线免费观看| 亚洲天堂国产精品一区在线| 18+在线观看网站| 欧美最新免费一区二区三区| 中文字幕av成人在线电影| 亚洲自拍偷在线| 久久婷婷人人爽人人干人人爱| 国产av不卡久久| 看非洲黑人一级黄片| 亚洲自拍偷在线| 精品人妻视频免费看| 国产精品,欧美在线| 欧美精品国产亚洲| 床上黄色一级片| 国产黄片视频在线免费观看| 99国产精品一区二区蜜桃av| 日韩成人av中文字幕在线观看| 美女xxoo啪啪120秒动态图| 舔av片在线| 亚洲最大成人av| 性插视频无遮挡在线免费观看| 久久久久网色| 午夜精品在线福利| 午夜激情欧美在线| 精品久久久久久成人av| kizo精华| 麻豆久久精品国产亚洲av| 亚洲中文字幕日韩| 大型黄色视频在线免费观看| 男女下面进入的视频免费午夜| 国产一区二区在线av高清观看| 亚洲av熟女| 日韩亚洲欧美综合| 午夜精品国产一区二区电影 | 青春草国产在线视频 | 夫妻性生交免费视频一级片| 又粗又爽又猛毛片免费看| 久久久成人免费电影| 亚洲欧美精品专区久久| 黄片无遮挡物在线观看| 深夜a级毛片| 欧美日韩精品成人综合77777| 亚洲av成人av| 久久精品影院6| 久久久久久大精品| 两个人视频免费观看高清| 国产成人影院久久av| 午夜激情欧美在线| 久久草成人影院| 午夜精品在线福利| 成人av在线播放网站| 日本撒尿小便嘘嘘汇集6| 亚洲天堂国产精品一区在线| 一个人看的www免费观看视频| 美女高潮的动态| 亚洲图色成人| 国产探花极品一区二区| 一区二区三区免费毛片| 亚洲成人中文字幕在线播放| 91麻豆精品激情在线观看国产| 97超视频在线观看视频| 久久久久久国产a免费观看| 99国产精品一区二区蜜桃av| 最后的刺客免费高清国语| 一级毛片我不卡| 最近手机中文字幕大全| 国产v大片淫在线免费观看| 精品久久久久久久久久久久久| 国产成人午夜福利电影在线观看| 久久精品国产亚洲av涩爱 | 草草在线视频免费看| 亚洲国产欧洲综合997久久,| 欧美一区二区国产精品久久精品| 校园人妻丝袜中文字幕| 日韩高清综合在线| 亚洲欧美中文字幕日韩二区| 桃色一区二区三区在线观看| 国产久久久一区二区三区| 啦啦啦韩国在线观看视频| 中文资源天堂在线| 欧美日韩综合久久久久久| 国产免费一级a男人的天堂| 波多野结衣高清无吗| 黄片wwwwww| 免费电影在线观看免费观看| 久久精品综合一区二区三区| 少妇猛男粗大的猛烈进出视频 | 亚洲av第一区精品v没综合| 毛片一级片免费看久久久久| 国产精品久久久久久精品电影小说 | 1000部很黄的大片| 伊人久久精品亚洲午夜| 少妇的逼水好多| 欧洲精品卡2卡3卡4卡5卡区| 99热6这里只有精品| 中国国产av一级| 99久久精品热视频| 波多野结衣高清无吗| 九九在线视频观看精品| 别揉我奶头 嗯啊视频| 亚洲国产精品成人久久小说 | 国产精品一二三区在线看| 六月丁香七月| 亚洲国产欧洲综合997久久,| 国产一区二区三区av在线 | 日韩强制内射视频| 国产精品国产三级国产av玫瑰| 国产精品久久久久久亚洲av鲁大| 亚洲电影在线观看av| 亚洲av二区三区四区| 麻豆久久精品国产亚洲av| 欧美精品一区二区大全| 久久这里只有精品中国| 亚洲精品国产成人久久av| 日韩欧美精品免费久久| 秋霞在线观看毛片| 天堂网av新在线| 成年女人看的毛片在线观看| 久久人人精品亚洲av| 国产精品一区二区三区四区久久| 欧美一区二区国产精品久久精品| 中国国产av一级| 欧美成人a在线观看| 亚洲国产色片| 极品教师在线视频| 午夜精品一区二区三区免费看| 欧美变态另类bdsm刘玥| 波野结衣二区三区在线| 久久欧美精品欧美久久欧美| 99热只有精品国产| 最近中文字幕高清免费大全6| 插阴视频在线观看视频| 亚洲av电影不卡..在线观看| 亚洲人成网站在线观看播放| 不卡一级毛片| 男人舔女人下体高潮全视频| 精品久久国产蜜桃| 高清毛片免费观看视频网站| 在线免费十八禁| 成人亚洲精品av一区二区| 又黄又爽又刺激的免费视频.| 国产探花极品一区二区| 国产成人精品久久久久久| 亚洲精品亚洲一区二区| 日本黄色视频三级网站网址| 久久精品国产自在天天线| 一边摸一边抽搐一进一小说| 久久久久久久亚洲中文字幕| 国产精品1区2区在线观看.| 一本—道久久a久久精品蜜桃钙片 精品乱码久久久久久99久播 | 性色avwww在线观看| 日日干狠狠操夜夜爽| 国产精品一区二区在线观看99 | 久久久久久大精品| 一进一出抽搐动态| 天堂av国产一区二区熟女人妻| 18+在线观看网站| 日韩欧美 国产精品| 久久精品夜夜夜夜夜久久蜜豆| 床上黄色一级片| 性插视频无遮挡在线免费观看| 日韩一区二区三区影片| 日本一本二区三区精品| 精品少妇黑人巨大在线播放 | 欧美+日韩+精品| 精品熟女少妇av免费看| 在线观看一区二区三区| 久久久成人免费电影| 日本免费一区二区三区高清不卡| 一进一出抽搐gif免费好疼| 亚洲精品自拍成人| 伦精品一区二区三区| 看黄色毛片网站| 中文资源天堂在线| 日韩欧美国产在线观看| 春色校园在线视频观看| 成人午夜高清在线视频| 免费看美女性在线毛片视频| 亚洲欧洲日产国产| 久久人人爽人人爽人人片va| 一本—道久久a久久精品蜜桃钙片 精品乱码久久久久久99久播 | 美女xxoo啪啪120秒动态图| 国产麻豆成人av免费视频| 免费观看精品视频网站| 99视频精品全部免费 在线| 最新中文字幕久久久久| 国产精品日韩av在线免费观看| 久久国内精品自在自线图片| 日本三级黄在线观看| 亚洲欧美日韩东京热| 村上凉子中文字幕在线| 中文字幕熟女人妻在线| 国产美女午夜福利| 国产色爽女视频免费观看| 白带黄色成豆腐渣| 久久精品国产自在天天线| 天美传媒精品一区二区| 99热全是精品| 日韩一区二区视频免费看| 精品熟女少妇av免费看| 国产精品国产三级国产av玫瑰| 午夜福利在线观看吧| 亚洲欧美精品综合久久99| 中文资源天堂在线| 亚洲精品久久久久久婷婷小说 | 日本-黄色视频高清免费观看| 国产成人91sexporn| 久久6这里有精品| 秋霞在线观看毛片| 少妇的逼水好多| 91午夜精品亚洲一区二区三区| 丰满乱子伦码专区| 中文字幕精品亚洲无线码一区| 免费一级毛片在线播放高清视频| 18禁黄网站禁片免费观看直播| or卡值多少钱| 非洲黑人性xxxx精品又粗又长| 国产欧美日韩精品一区二区| av天堂中文字幕网| 国产成年人精品一区二区| 亚洲最大成人手机在线| 欧美潮喷喷水| 亚洲激情五月婷婷啪啪| 最近视频中文字幕2019在线8| 精品无人区乱码1区二区| 国产午夜精品一二区理论片| 日本与韩国留学比较| 乱人视频在线观看| 国产精品伦人一区二区| 两性午夜刺激爽爽歪歪视频在线观看| 成人国产麻豆网| 男人的好看免费观看在线视频| 国产大屁股一区二区在线视频| 不卡一级毛片| 18禁在线播放成人免费| 亚洲欧美精品综合久久99| 国产高清不卡午夜福利| 日韩欧美三级三区| av卡一久久| 又爽又黄a免费视频| 熟女电影av网| 亚洲精品粉嫩美女一区| 亚洲av不卡在线观看| 亚洲中文字幕日韩| 亚洲内射少妇av| 午夜激情欧美在线| 尾随美女入室| 色综合亚洲欧美另类图片| 在线观看美女被高潮喷水网站| 啦啦啦啦在线视频资源| 波野结衣二区三区在线| 国产成人91sexporn| 亚洲国产色片| 人人妻人人看人人澡| 欧美精品一区二区大全| 观看美女的网站| 色尼玛亚洲综合影院| 变态另类成人亚洲欧美熟女| 波多野结衣高清作品| 成人二区视频| 欧美极品一区二区三区四区| 高清毛片免费看| 亚洲中文字幕一区二区三区有码在线看| 国产伦精品一区二区三区视频9| 亚洲精品亚洲一区二区| 亚洲国产精品久久男人天堂| 黄色一级大片看看| www日本黄色视频网| 国产精品嫩草影院av在线观看| 亚洲av中文字字幕乱码综合| 黄片wwwwww| 毛片女人毛片| 色5月婷婷丁香| 婷婷六月久久综合丁香| 亚洲欧美清纯卡通| 亚洲成av人片在线播放无| 色综合亚洲欧美另类图片| 国产精品嫩草影院av在线观看| 国产伦一二天堂av在线观看| 亚洲国产欧洲综合997久久,| 麻豆av噜噜一区二区三区| av.在线天堂| 日本av手机在线免费观看| 99热这里只有是精品50| 久久99蜜桃精品久久| 久久6这里有精品| 99久久成人亚洲精品观看| 2022亚洲国产成人精品| 性色avwww在线观看| 日韩成人伦理影院| 免费电影在线观看免费观看| 日韩一区二区三区影片| 亚洲性久久影院| 精华霜和精华液先用哪个| 亚洲av二区三区四区| 国产精品一区二区三区四区免费观看| 99热网站在线观看| 秋霞在线观看毛片| 国产精品乱码一区二三区的特点| 国产成年人精品一区二区| 性欧美人与动物交配| 寂寞人妻少妇视频99o| 免费看美女性在线毛片视频| 精品久久久噜噜| 精品人妻视频免费看| 午夜精品在线福利| 九草在线视频观看| 欧美性猛交╳xxx乱大交人| 又黄又爽又刺激的免费视频.| 精品久久久久久久久亚洲| 国产亚洲av嫩草精品影院| 少妇的逼水好多| 亚洲美女视频黄频| 人妻少妇偷人精品九色| 婷婷亚洲欧美| 精品午夜福利在线看| 99热全是精品| 人妻夜夜爽99麻豆av| 欧美成人a在线观看| 国产大屁股一区二区在线视频| 自拍偷自拍亚洲精品老妇| av卡一久久| 久久久久久久久久成人| 精品午夜福利在线看| 精品日产1卡2卡| 国产免费一级a男人的天堂| 岛国在线免费视频观看| av黄色大香蕉| 三级国产精品欧美在线观看| 女人十人毛片免费观看3o分钟| a级一级毛片免费在线观看| 亚洲av男天堂| 美女高潮的动态| 国产极品精品免费视频能看的| 18禁在线播放成人免费| 啦啦啦韩国在线观看视频| 久久婷婷人人爽人人干人人爱| 人妻系列 视频| 成人毛片a级毛片在线播放| 国产成人影院久久av| 亚洲无线观看免费| 精品午夜福利在线看| 国产91av在线免费观看| 国产三级中文精品| 亚洲五月天丁香| 91精品一卡2卡3卡4卡| 又粗又硬又长又爽又黄的视频 | 国产日本99.免费观看| .国产精品久久| 在线观看美女被高潮喷水网站| 黄色欧美视频在线观看| 久久这里只有精品中国| 成人二区视频| 日产精品乱码卡一卡2卡三| 久久久国产成人免费| 成人亚洲欧美一区二区av| 日本免费a在线| 少妇的逼水好多| 国产成年人精品一区二区| 国内久久婷婷六月综合欲色啪| 国产午夜精品久久久久久一区二区三区| 精品一区二区三区视频在线| 国产熟女欧美一区二区| 国产精品精品国产色婷婷| 国产成人a区在线观看| 欧美日韩在线观看h| 狂野欧美白嫩少妇大欣赏| 欧美日韩一区二区视频在线观看视频在线 | 亚洲av电影不卡..在线观看| 久久久久久九九精品二区国产| 一个人观看的视频www高清免费观看| 特级一级黄色大片| 欧美性猛交黑人性爽| 国产在线精品亚洲第一网站| 午夜a级毛片| 国产精品一区www在线观看| 插逼视频在线观看| 99久久无色码亚洲精品果冻| 人妻制服诱惑在线中文字幕| 国产一区二区亚洲精品在线观看| 观看免费一级毛片| avwww免费| 欧美成人免费av一区二区三区| 天天躁夜夜躁狠狠久久av| 美女cb高潮喷水在线观看| 成年版毛片免费区| 99国产精品一区二区蜜桃av| 成人永久免费在线观看视频| or卡值多少钱| 麻豆一二三区av精品| АⅤ资源中文在线天堂| 久久久a久久爽久久v久久| 亚洲欧美成人综合另类久久久 | 夜夜夜夜夜久久久久| 亚洲精品亚洲一区二区| 51国产日韩欧美| 人妻制服诱惑在线中文字幕| 你懂的网址亚洲精品在线观看 | 爱豆传媒免费全集在线观看| 亚洲七黄色美女视频| 干丝袜人妻中文字幕| 小说图片视频综合网站| 校园人妻丝袜中文字幕| 欧美最黄视频在线播放免费| 97超视频在线观看视频| 中文在线观看免费www的网站| 黄片wwwwww| 中文字幕制服av| 男女下面进入的视频免费午夜| 高清毛片免费看| 亚洲欧美成人综合另类久久久 | 好男人在线观看高清免费视频| 亚洲中文字幕一区二区三区有码在线看| 国产成人影院久久av| 精品不卡国产一区二区三区| 亚洲欧美清纯卡通| 国产亚洲精品久久久久久毛片| 最后的刺客免费高清国语| 全区人妻精品视频| 亚洲va在线va天堂va国产| 日本成人三级电影网站| 一边摸一边抽搐一进一小说| 亚洲av二区三区四区| 毛片一级片免费看久久久久| 色综合色国产| 久久韩国三级中文字幕| 国产精品一区二区三区四区免费观看| 嫩草影院精品99| 日韩欧美在线乱码| 舔av片在线| 亚洲无线观看免费| 美女xxoo啪啪120秒动态图| 日韩欧美在线乱码| 乱人视频在线观看| 日韩在线高清观看一区二区三区| 日韩强制内射视频| av在线亚洲专区| 欧美性感艳星| 国产亚洲精品av在线| av在线天堂中文字幕| 国产探花在线观看一区二区| 欧美bdsm另类| 免费看av在线观看网站| 亚洲乱码一区二区免费版| 日本一二三区视频观看| 看免费成人av毛片| 免费搜索国产男女视频| 白带黄色成豆腐渣| 久久午夜福利片| 欧美最新免费一区二区三区| 国模一区二区三区四区视频| 日本黄色视频三级网站网址| 日本欧美国产在线视频| 欧美精品一区二区大全| 国产精品美女特级片免费视频播放器| 日韩欧美 国产精品| 51国产日韩欧美| 久久99精品国语久久久| 日本撒尿小便嘘嘘汇集6| 日本五十路高清| 99久国产av精品| 在线观看一区二区三区| 国产乱人偷精品视频| 97超视频在线观看视频| 欧美最黄视频在线播放免费| 欧美一区二区国产精品久久精品| 日韩欧美在线乱码| 美女xxoo啪啪120秒动态图| 两性午夜刺激爽爽歪歪视频在线观看| 激情 狠狠 欧美| 一个人看视频在线观看www免费| 成人午夜高清在线视频| h日本视频在线播放| 国产成人a∨麻豆精品| 日本成人三级电影网站| 亚洲精品国产av成人精品| 国产免费一级a男人的天堂| 可以在线观看的亚洲视频| 神马国产精品三级电影在线观看| 韩国av在线不卡| 久久99蜜桃精品久久| 如何舔出高潮|