• <tr id="yyy80"></tr>
  • <sup id="yyy80"></sup>
  • <tfoot id="yyy80"><noscript id="yyy80"></noscript></tfoot>
  • 99热精品在线国产_美女午夜性视频免费_国产精品国产高清国产av_av欧美777_自拍偷自拍亚洲精品老妇_亚洲熟女精品中文字幕_www日本黄色视频网_国产精品野战在线观看 ?

    One size fits all? Contract farming among broiler producers in China

    2018-02-05 07:11:00HUANGZeyingXUYingZENGDiWANGChenWANGJimin
    Journal of Integrative Agriculture 2018年2期
    關鍵詞:詞頻保護措施現(xiàn)行

    HUANG Ze-ying, XU Ying, ZENG Di, WANG Chen, WANG Ji-min

    1 Institute of Agricultural Economics and Development, Chinese Academy of Agricultural Sciences, Beijing 100081, P.R.China

    2 Centre for Global Food and Resources, University of Adelaide, Adelaide 5005, Australia

    1. lntroduction

    Agricultural contract can be generally defined as an agreement between producer and buyer which specifies the price of an agricultural commodity to be delivered at a certain point of time in the future (Harwoodet al. 1999). In the past decades, contract farming has observed increasing popularity in agrarian economies (Glover 1984; Nguyenet al. 2015). The expansion of contract farming is jointly triggered by increasing demand of agricultural products due to income and population growth, and increasing productivity given modern agricultural technologies in production, postharvest processing and distribution (Barrettet al. 2012).With potential benefits such as market assurance, input access for producers and risk mitigation for downstream contractors, contract farming is at the heart of agricultural value chain modernisation in developing countries (Glover 1990; Oya 2012; Martinez-Gomezet al. 2013).

    As most of the poor in developing countries are small agricultural producers, the welfare impacts of contract farming on smallholders have attracted growing attention in search of policy implications (Nguyenet al. 2015). Existing literature, however, provides only inconsistent findings.Political economy analyses tend to agree that smallholders have weak bargaining powervis-à-vismonopsonistic contractors, especially if they have few alternatives of livelihood (Grosh 1994; Little 1994). For this reason,smallholders might have seen little welfare improvement from contract farming (Merryet al. 2004; Sivramkrishna and Jyotishi 2008), and likely become quasi-employees as they yield to the downstream contractor in production decision making (Reardon and Barrett 2000). Moreover, contractors may favour larger producers while poorer growers could be marginalised (Little and Watts 1994; Singh 2002; Dev and Rao 2005). Negative externalities may further occur(Welsh 2009). While these critics seem appealing, a growing number of studies from a purely empirical perspective actually suggest the opposite: smallholders in developing countries do benefit from contract farming in terms of income (Bolwig and Gibbonet al. 2009; Miyataet al. 2009;Bellemare 2012), return to capital (Simmonset al. 2005),food security (Bellemare and Novak 2015), and women’s employment (Raynolds 2002). These conflicting results can hardly assist policy decisions aiming to improve welfare through contract farming, and more evidence is needed to build up external validity.

    Agricultural production in China has observed substantial changes in the past decades. The dietary structure has been shifting from plant-based to animal-based foods as a result of income growth (Fukase and Martin 2016), which is further magnified by population increase, yet the production behaviour in the poultry industry remains much unknown.In this article, we aim to narrow this knowledge gap through the investigation of contract farming participation of small broiler producers in China using a nationally representative survey. During the past decades, poultry industry in China has observed significant growth and has undergone rapid structural change from smallholder-dominated production to large-scale contract farming (Xie and Marchant 2015).Consequently, the poultry sector is no longer dominated by smallholders and many of them who used to keep broilers as a sideline activity have given up production (Ke and Han 2007). Remaining farmers generally specialise in broiler production (Xinet al. 2016). The welfare implications of broiler contract farming in China have not been formally analysed, though contract farming has grown rapidly in China (Guoet al. 2007), and empirical literature occasionally reports increased profitability for producers in neighbouring countries (Simmonset al. 2005; Narayanan 2014). The structural change and coexistence of small and large producers jointly provide a unique opportunity to analyse smallholder participation in contract farming and associated welfare results.

    We approach this topic from both descriptive and quantitative perspectives. We first summarise the characteristics of surveyed households as well as the market prices and costs in their broiler production, the latter of which suggests that contract farming might not be optimal for small producers through cost-benefit comparisons. We then proceed with the estimation of a multinomial logistic regression model to reveal how farmers’ choices among individual farming and three types of contract farming are associated with their socioeconomic characteristics, where the possible endogeneity of broiler production is corrected for using a control function approach. It is found that farm size significantly and consistently explains the variation in these choices. We finally discuss the implications of ourfindings, and conclude our analysis specifically with strategic suggestions for small broiler producers.

    2. Analytical framework

    While the contradictory welfare results in literature may be puzzling, a closer look reveals that contract farming usually leads to welfare improvements where most producers are smallholders (Simmonset al. 2005; Bolwig and Gibbon 2009; Miyataet al. 2009; Bellemare 2012; Bellemare and Novak 2015). This is intuitive because, if the market is mostly supplied by smallholders who face similar production costs, contracts would only occur if the contracted price is high enough to incentivise most smallholders to participate.However, when large holders are also existent, there could be some room for arbitrage for the downstream contractor,and smallholders would therefore lose. This is likely the case when the contracted price is large enough to attract large holders with their economies of scale and thus lower per unit production costs, but is not sufficient to offset the higher production costs faced by smallholders. Hence, the smallholder welfare impacts of contract farming may vary with the supply-side market structure.

    Fig. 1 depicts two different scenarios: with homogeneous producers (smallholders) and with heterogeneous producers (both small and large holders). In each graph,the upper block shows the cumulative percentage of total market production plotted against the cumulative percentage of the corresponding producers ranked by farm size from small to large, which is comparable to the Lorenz curve income distribution. The lower block,on the other hand, shows the average production cost among producers ranked in exactly the same manner.Therefore, with homogeneous producers, the cumulative production share curve is the 45-degree line and the average production cost is the same for all producers, as shown in Fig. 1-A. While with heterogeneous producers,the cumulative production share curve is below the 45-degree line as large holders produce disproportionally more than smallholders, and the average production cost is downward sloping given economies of scale that lowers the average cost when production increases. In both cases,for a certain among of production is to be delivered to the downstream contractor. With homogeneous producers,the contracted price is equal to the average production cost (a higher contracted price is not as profitable for the contractor while a lower contracted price generates a loss for farmers and thus may not be accepted). Producers ranked from b to c participate in contract farming in this case. With heterogeneous producers, however, only a small number of large producers participate in contract farming (from b to c), whose average production costs are below the contracted price, yet participation is not profitable for smaller producers ranked from a to b as their costs are higher than the contracted price. These smaller producers may therefore opt out of contract farming and look for alternative marketing opportunities to obtain higher profits.

    Although the above literature has intensively explored the welfare implications of contract farming in a variety of countries with almost homogeneous smallholders, less is known about possible impacts with the coexistence of small and large holders, and how expected profitability could affect the participation of smallholders in contract farming. This information, however, is needed to assist policy designs aimed at improving smallholder welfare and ensuring reasonable allocation of benefits associated with contract farming. With the simultaneous presence of heterogeneous farmers, the broiler industry in China is an ideal opportunity to analyse the smallholder welfare in this regard.

    Fig. 1 Contract farming with different supply-side market structures. A, contract farming with homogeneous producers (smallholders).B, contract farming with heterogeneous producers (small and large holders).

    3. Data and method

    The current study is facilitated by a recent national household survey of Chinese broiler producers implemented from June to August, 2015. Six provinces (autonomous region) are covered: Jilin, Hebei, Shandong, Hubei,Guangdong and Guangxi, which cover a wide spectrum of aggregate broiler production levels in the country and jointly represent 43% broiler meat production in China.The first three provinces are in northern China, while the latter three provinces (autonomous region) are in southern China. Stratified sampling strategy has been used for data collection. Within each stratum (province), four to five broiler-producing towns were randomly selected from a list of all broiler-producing towns provided by local agricultural experimental stations, and broiler producers were then randomly selected from producing household lists provided by the village committees. The survey was implemented through face-to-face interviews with farm household heads by the research team that consists of one professor and four doctoral students in the research field of poultry farm management. In our survey, 27 towns were selected with 15 farmers from each town, generating a sample frame of 405 broiler producers. Of these farmers, five refused to participate in the interviews, reducing the total sample to 400. However, in many cases the interviews were also interrupted mid-way through, or cancelled if the farmer was called away and an alternative time could not be identified. In the end, 373 questionnaires were conducted.367 questionnaires were finally deemed as complete with all information appropriately recorded, suggesting a valid response rate of 98.39%. These 367 producers thus serve as the full sample of our analysis.

    Three types of contracts are existent in our data: 1) firm contract, 2) cooperative contract, and 3) hybrid contract.Firm contract (firm+producer) is the most popular contract type, which occurs directly between the downstream processor (firm) and broiler producer. Cooperative contracts(cooperative+producer) are less common yet still existent in many areas, with the downstream contractor being the agricultural marketing cooperative rather than the firm.Unlike the firm, an agricultural marketing cooperative is an entity jointly owned and operated by producers, which pools their individual resources to facilitate final marketing.Hybrid contracts (firm+cooperative+producer) have also been observed in the last decade among Chinese broiler producers due to the beliefs that individual farmers can barely negotiate with large downstream contractors but agricultural cooperatives can generally represent farmers’economic interests. In a hybrid contract, the agricultural cooperative negotiates and contracts with the downstreamfirm on behalf of individual farmers who collectively operate the cooperative, while the agreement between the cooperative and individual farmers are pre-arranged.Therefore, the hybrid contract consists of two contracts,one between the cooperative and the firm, and the other between individual farmers and the cooperative. We further differentiate cooperative contract from hybrid contract by the market role of the cooperative. In the cooperative contract,the cooperative takes full responsibility of final-stage broiler marketing and directly deals with consumers (e.g., individual consumers, restaurants, school cafeterias); while in the hybrid contract, the cooperative does not participate in finalstage broiler marketing but contracts with a downstream business for further broiler processing.

    These contract types differ in strengths and weaknesses.While firm contract is perhaps the most straightforward type,it is often criticized as exploitive due to the weak bargaining power of individual producers (Grosh 1994; Little 1994).Cooperative contract, while voicing the needs of producers,can be inadvertently constrained by their lack of knowledge,skills, market information or appropriate business strategies.As a comparison, hybrid contract can help build a more stable relationship among producers and downstream agents as it both strengthens the collective bargaining power of producers and eases market information transmission back to producers given clear downstream needs, yet in reality it is more difficult to establish given the multiple parties involved and the difficulties of negotiation.

    In our survey, all the contracts were written and were signed before broiler production. Focus group study suggests farmers generally believe written contracts are better than oral ones in terms of securing the contracted marketing channel and clarifying terms and conditions(thereby facilitating easier conflict resolution in case of need). To create a contract, the downstream contractor first offers the written contract that specifies the quality, price, and production details including the time of transaction. Focus group study suggests product quality is a major incentive to use contracts, which accords with earlier literature (e.g.,Guoet al. 2007). Then negotiation occurs and the contract is signed when terms and conditions are agreed upon, and so the contracted price can vary among producers. In each contract type, the downstream contractor partly shares some of the responsibilities of broiler breed provision, technology training, consulting, and disease control practices, which results in looser contract structures as compared to vertical integration commonly observed in horticultural production.However, the contract relationship is reasonably stable as most farmers contract with the same downstream entity over the years given that the number of downstream contractors are limited in most localities. The nonparticipants of broiler production contracts always sold their broilers directly to the market in our data.

    Table 1 presents the summary statistics of the full samples and subsamples broken down by participation status of broiler contract farming and contract types.Household head characteristics, farm characteristics and broiler production practices are respectively presented in three panels. Among surveyed broiler producers, 59.4%(218 producers) participated in firm contract, whereas much fewer participated in either cooperative (46 producers)or hybrid (25 producers) contracts. The remaining 78 producers (21.3%) directly sold their broilers to the market without any contract engagement. While most household head and farm characteristics were very similar across these subsamples, firm contract participants did appear to be more likely female-headed and less likely Communist Party members, while hybrid contract participants were the most educated group with the lowest proportion of risk-averse producers. Nonparticipants of broiler contract farming looked rather alike, except that they possessed an above-average education level and there were fewer village cadres among them. Regarding farm characteristics, hybrid contract participants had the largest land area, which was about twice that of firm and cooperative contract participants and one third larger than that of nonparticipants. Moreover,nonparticipants were more likely to raise local broiler breeds and to be close to major markets. Most of these discrepancies, however, are small.

    More interesting patterns can be seen from a simple cost-benefit analysis of broiler production among surveyed farmers. Nonparticipants had the smallest annual production,which is about half that of the contract participants, which accords with earlier observations that contract farming might favour larger producers (Little and Watts 1994; Singh 2002; Dev and Rao 2005). On the other hand, the annual production of hybrid contract participants was the largest.Moreover, although hybrid contract participants realised the smallest profit per broiler, their total broiler income was still the highest among all subgroups given their largest annual production.

    A comparison among all subgroups further suggests that economies of scale are evident, as annual production and per broiler production cost rank in exactly reversed order.The average broiler weight at farm gate is the smallest for nonparticipants and their per broiler production cost is the highest, which could be partly due to the fact that there was no technological support from downstream contractors.However, the broiler prices they received directly from the market were substantially higher than those offered by contractors, and therefore the profit per broiler for nonparticipants (6.090 CNY or 0.968 USD in 2015) was averaged 327% that of all contract participants. As a result,even with the smallest annual production, the total broiler income of nonparticipants was not necessarily lower than(e.g., firm) contract participants. This is consistent with earlier findings (Verhaegen and Van Huylenbroeck 2001),and these observations imply that it might not be profitable for the former to participate in contract farming. To test this,we implement a simple counterfactual exercise by replacing the individual broiler market prices nonparticipants received with the province-level average contract price participants received. In that case, 74 out of 78 nonparticipants would have negative profits if they were participants, which confirms the above speculation.

    The above observation accords with our hypothesis that contract farming could have opposite welfare results between smaller and larger producers. To investigate the role of farm size in broiler contract farming participation,there is a need to further implement quantitative analysis where multiple factors are simultaneously controlled for. It is towards such analysis that we now turn.

    Table 1 Descriptive statistics of full samples and subsamples by contract type

    4. Results

    We employ multinomial logistic regression modelling to investigate the possible effect of farm size in broiler contract farming participation. Multinomial logistic regression is specifically useful in predicting the probabilities of mutually exclusive discrete choices with a set of independent variables (Greene 2012). In our case, the four discrete choices are firm contract participation, cooperative contract participation, hybrid contract participation and nonparticipation. Multinomial logistic regression is appropriate in our analysis because on one hand, a simple logistic regression with the binary outcome of participation/nonparticipation would not be capable to differentiate possible heterogeneity among choices over three contract types. On the other hand, contract participation decision and contract choice could not be separated as both were made before broiler production (or a nested logistic model would be more appropriate). Independent variables in our analysis include household head characteristics, farm characteristics and annual broiler production as described in Table 1. Broiler sales price, production cost and profit measures are not included as predictors because they were realised during or after the production process, and could not logically affect the participation decision or contract choice made before production. Neither included is broiler breed,which is usually provided by the downstream contractors if the producer participates in contract farming and is not a separate decision. However, annual production is included as it is the best available indicator of economies of scale, which might not change much during a single year.Finally, town dummies are included to capture any possible unobserved heterogeneity across localities.

    Empirical estimation of the multinomial logistic regression relies on the assumption of independence of irrelevant alternatives. It states that the odds, or relative probability, of preferring one choice over another are independent from the presence or absence of other alternatives, which therefore can be considered as “irrelevant”. We proceed with formal Hausman-type tests to see whether this assumption holds since the violation of which could invalidate our results, andfind that it does.

    現(xiàn)行國家評價體系中一級指標還有“保護措施”一項,用以評價保護措施的合理性、完善性和執(zhí)行力度。由于本文詞頻分析中出現(xiàn)的與保護管理相關的“管理、治理”二詞占比較低,故沒有將“保護措施”作為一級指標,而是在三級指標中出現(xiàn)。

    A potential concern of direct maximum likelihood estimation of the multinomial logistic model regards the possible endogeneity of annual broiler production, a decision made by the producer, which could result in biased and inconsistent estimates. Endogeneity has been recognized in contract choices in agricultural production (Ackerberg and Botticini 2002), yet addressing endogeneity in a multinomial logistic regression is technically very difficult (Wooldridge 2015). In our case, we employ the two-step control function estimation procedure proposed by Wooldridge (2015).In the first step, we estimate simple linear regression using an excluded instrument and covariates against the endogenous variable of annual broiler production, and obtain the residuals. In the second step, we then estimate a multinomial logistic model using the residual as the control function along with covariates. Standard errors are finally obtained using bootstrapping.

    The excluded instrument in our analysis is the area of broiler production facilities, which should intuitively affect annual broiler production but not affect broiler contract choice other than through annual production, thereby meeting the criteria of the instrumental variable. The pairwise correlation coefficient between the instrument and annual broiler production is 0.57, probably not as high as one may speculate, because 1) the different practices among producers lead to varying broiler densities during production,and 2) certain off-farm employment opportunities have prevented the broiler production facilities to reach their full capacities. In the first-step regression, the overallF-value is 41.76 (with aP-value of 0.000), suggesting the excluded instrument is reasonably strong.

    In the multinomial logistic regression, nonparticipation is set as the default outcome. Moreover, we should focus on the average partial effects of covariates to ease the interpretation of results. Table 2 presents the average partial effects obtained by estimating the average structural function (Wooldridge 2015). The overall model specification is statistically significant at the 1% level, suggesting all covariates together successfully explain part of the outcome variations.

    Among all covariates, annual production, which captures economies of scale, is statistically significant in all contract choices. This is in line with recent literature (Abebeet al.2016). Specifically, the probabilities of participating in firm,cooperative and hybrid contracts would be 0.010, 0.013 and 0.005 higher as annual production level increases by 1 000 broilers. While the average partial effects are small, the actual differences may not necessarily be. The interquartile range in annual production in our data is 30 000 broilers,which implies that the probabilities of participating in each type of contract can be 30, 39 and 15% higher for the median large producer (75% percentile of annual production–45 000 broilers) than for the median small producer (25%percentile of annual production –15 000 broilers). Thesefindings confirm our earlier observation that smallholders would be less likely to participate in broiler contract farming.

    Several patterns of the associations between other covariates and contract choices are also worth discussion.Being a village cadre encourages firm contract participation,while being a Communist Party member discourages it. In China, village cadres are usually experienced,entrepreneurial and more capable farmers who take the lead in economic activities, while Party members tend to be conservative individuals who are more likely to follow instructions of the local government. As very few producers were both village cadres and Party members in our data,these contradictory effects could simply reflect the conflicting roles of these engagements in this foremost contract type.While education does not seem to stimulate contract farming in general, better educated producers are less likely to participate in cooperative contract, where the cooperative is run by farmers and represent their economic interests.Moreover, risk-averse producers are found more likely to participate in either firm or cooperative contract, which is also intuitive given the more secure marketing channel with contract farming, though such association is not seen with hybrid contract participation. Most other covariates do not seem to be correlated with contract choices.

    Table 2 Multinomial logistic control function estimation of broiler contract choices (n=367)1)

    5. Discussion

    These findings further imply that it could be a rational choice for small producers to opt out of contract farming,which differs from the existing concern that they might be passively excluded from participation given that downstream contractors would prefer large producers (Little and Watts 1994; Singh 2002; Dev and Rao 2005). The underlying belief of the latter argument is that contract farming could potentially benefit all producers, and therefore nonparticipation would result in undesirable welfare loss for small producers,which is not the case in our study. Specifically, the poultry industry in China has been through rapid structural change where farmers increasingly specialise in broiler production,leading to the coexistence of small and large producers(Xie and Marchant 2015), which would largely explain the unprofitability of smaller producers in contract farming. This coexistence could be temporary and might fade over time given the progressive specialisation in broiler production and the fast increase of productivity among remaining broiler producers (Xinet al. 2016). However, our results are still of policy importance because, although broiler industry in China has been transitioning from smallholder-dominated production to large-scale contract farming, the ongoing process may take a long time and many small broiler producers are still expected to exist in the foreseeable future. Moreover, our data may also mirror the future market patterns of smallholder agriculture which is widely existent in agrarian economies and yet to be modernised. Hence,rather than contradicting recent literature that documents positive smallholder welfare impacts in those economies(e.g., Simmonset al. 2005; Bolwig and Gibbon 2009; Miyataet al. 2009; Bellemare 2012; Bellemare and Novak 2015),the current study complements it in terms of forecasting possible smallholder welfare scenarios that might occur as markets evolve.

    As contract farming may benefit smallholders only if they provide most of market supply, a key question is about the future of smallholders given the increasing prevalence of contract farming with agricultural modernisation.Expectedly, not all small producers would continue broiler production, increase productivity or participate in contract farming. While the welfare consequences of quitting broiler production are not necessarily undesirable, especially when outside opportunities are more profitable, possible impacts on remaining small producers still demand more attention.Specifically, as producers are price-driven, it is necessary to investigate how evolving market prices affect smallholder welfare.

    One interesting observation in our data is that the market prices received by nonparticipants of contract farming were much higher than the contracted prices for participants(Table 1). While middlemen’s profits might partly explain this difference, more can be revealed through a simple comparison of broiler breeds of nonparticipants. Among 76 nonparticipants, 33 produced broilers of improved breeds and 45 produced broilers of local breeds. The average price received by the former group (11.67 CNY, or 1.86 USD in 2015) is significantly lower than that of the latter group (19.28 CNY, or 3.07 USD in 2015,P-value through pairwiset-test: 0.003). This pattern, along with the fact that nonparticipants produce broilers of local breeds the most (Table 1), confirms earlier observation that Chinese consumers generally prefer “l(fā)ocal” chicken, which are free-range, slowly-growing with poor feed conversion, but with better meat quality in terms of flavour, tenderness,fat deposition, muscle fibre composition, as well as visual appearances (Yang and Jiang 2005). Therefore, consumers’willingness to pay for those “l(fā)ocal” chicken could be much higher. The implication of this consumer preference can be more profound when placed in the context regarding the future of small producers. A possible strategy is to meet these market needs by specialising in “l(fā)ocal” chicken or poultry products for which small producers possess a comparative advantage. This has already taken place in multiple food sectors. For example, organic food production has experienced an annual farmland increase of 8.9%between 2001 and 2011 to meet the increasing demand(Paull 2011). In the broiler industry, possible opportunities similarly exist for not only organic but also free-range chicken given their price privileges (Husaket al. 2008). Even in developed countries, the market opportunity for both organic and free range poultry products is yet to be fully developed(Castelliniet al. 2008). Specialising in these products could therefore be a possible long-term business strategy for small broiler producers given that contract farming is not profitable.

    6. Conclusion

    We investigate whether contract farming is a financially good option for small broiler producers using a recent nationally representative survey in China. In contrast with many recent studies, we find that contract farming does not benefit small producers in face of larger competitors, the latter of which assume lower production costs given their economies of scale. Descriptive and quantitative analyses further show that small producers were not disadvantageous in terms of socioeconomic characteristics. Certainly, low profits made them opt out of contract farming, given the much higher prices they received from directly selling to the market.Therefore, the current study complements recent empirical literature in extending the almost homogeneous supplyside market structure to cover the coexistence of small and large producers, and conclude that contract farming may not be able to effectively improve smallholder welfare in the latter case.

    We further discuss that small broiler producers may consider alternative opportunities to continue operating in the poultry industry, such as specialising in organic and free-range chicken, which better utilises their comparative advantages. Full cost-benefit analysis of these strategies,however, is beyond the scope of this study. Data limitations further exclude us from investigating the smallholder welfare dynamics of contract farming over time, especially with market structure evolvement from homogeneous small producers to the coexistence of small and large producers.As a first study on broiler contract farming in China, ourfindings only speak to this specific industry and more research is needed to establish external validity. These remaining issues are open for further investigation that could build on the current analysis to better derive policy implications regarding the welfare impacts of contract farming.

    Acknowledgements

    This study is supported by the earmarked fund for the Agricultural Science and Technology Innovation Program,Chinese Academy of Agricultural Sciences (ASTIPIAED-2017) and the Modern Agro-industry Technology Research System, the Ministry of Agriculture of China(CARS-42-G24). We thank Prof. Liu Chunfang, Dr. E Yuzhou and Miss Zhou Rui from Chinese Academy of Agricultural Sciences for their assistance in survey data collection and the supports of staffs from broilers test stations in Hebei,Jilin, Shandong, Guangxi, Hubei and Guangdong.

    Abebe G K, Bijman J, Royer A. 2016. Are middlemen facilitators or barriers to improve smallholders’ welfare in rural economies? Empirical evidence from Ethiopia.Journal of Rural Studies, 43, 203–213.

    Ackerberg D A, Botticini M. 2002. Endogenous matching and the empirical determinants of contract form.Journal of Political Economy, 110, 564–591.

    Barrett C B, Bachke M E, Bellemare M F, Michelson H C,Narayanan S, Walker T F. 2012. Smallholder participation in contract farming: Comparative evidence from five countries.World Development, 40, 715–730.

    Bellemare M F. 2012. As you sow, so shall you reap: The welfare impacts of contract farming.World Development,40, 1418–1434.

    Bellemare M F, Novak L. 2015. Contract farming and food security.American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 99,357–378.

    Bolwig S, Gibbon P. 2009. The economics of smallholder organic contract farming in tropical Africa.World Development, 37,1094–1104.

    Castellini C, Berri C, Le Bihan-Duval E, Martino G. 2008.Qualitative attributes and consumer perception of organic and free-range poultry meat.World’s Poultry Science Journal, 64, 500–512.

    Dev S M, Rao N C. 2005. Food processing and contract farming in Andhra Pradesh: A small farmer perspective.Economic and Political Weekly, 40, 2705–2713.

    Fukase E, Martin W. 2016. Who will feed China in the 21st century? Income growth and food demand and supply in China.Journal of Agricultural Economics, 67, 3–23.

    Glover D. 1990. Contract farming and outgrower schemes in east and southern Africa.Journal of Agricultural Economics,41,303–315.

    Glover D J. 1984. Contract farming and smallholder outgrower schemes in less developed countries.World Development,12, 1143–1157.

    Greene W H. 2012.Econometric Analysis. 7th ed. Prentice Hall,Upper Saddle River. pp. 763–766.

    Grosh B. 1994. Contract farming in Africa: An application of the new institutional economies.Journal of African Economics,3, 231–261.

    Guo H, Jolly R W, Zhu J. 2007. Contract farming in China:Perspectives of farm households and agribusiness firms.Comparative Economic Studies, 49, 285–312.

    Harwood J, Heifner R, Coble K, Perry J, Somwaru A. 1999.Managing Risk in Farming: Concepts, Research, and Analysis.Market and Trade Economics Division and Resource Economics Division, Economic Research Service,U.S. Department of Agriculture. Agricultural Economic Report No. 774.

    Husak R L, Sebranek J G, Bregendahl K. 2008. A survey of commercially available broilers marketed as organic, freerange, and conventional broilers for cooked meat yields,meat composition, and relative value.Poultry Science,87, 2367–2376.

    Ke B, Han Y. 2007. Poultry sector in China: Structural changes during the past decade and future trends. In: Thieme O,Pilling D, eds.,Poultry in the 21st Century: Avian Influenza and Beyond. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Bangkok, Rome, Italy. pp. 1–33.

    Little P. 1994. Contract farming and the development question.In: Little P, Watts M, eds.,Living Under Contract: Contract Farming and Agrarian Transformation in Sub-Saharan Africa. University of Wisconsin Press, Madison.

    Little P D, Watts M J. 1994.Living Under Contract: Contract Farming and Agrarian Transformation in the Sub-Saharan Africa. University of Wisconsin Press, Madison.

    Martinez-Gomez F, Aboites-Manrique G, Constance D H.2013. Neoliberal restructuring, neoregulation, and the Mexican poultry industry.Agriculture and Human Values,30, 495–510.

    Merry F D, Sheikh P A, Mcgrath D G. 2004. The role of informal contracts in the growth of small cattle herds on thefloodplains of the Lower Amazon.Agriculture and Human Values, 21, 377–386.

    Miyata S, Minot N, Hu D. 2009. Impact of contract farming on income: Linking small farmers, packers, and supermarkets in China.World Development, 37, 1781–1790.

    Narayanan S. 2014. Profits from participation in high value agriculture: Evidence of heterogeneous benefits in contract farming schemes in Southern India.Food Policy, 44,142–157.

    Nguyen A T, Dzator J, Nadolny A. 2015. Does contract farming improve productivity and income of farmers? A review of theory and evidence.Journal of Developing Areas, 49,531–538.

    Oya C. 2012. Contract farming in Sub-Saharan Africa: A survey of approaches, debates and issues.Journal of Agrarian Change, 12, 1–33.

    Paull J. 2011. The Uptake of organic agriculture: A decade of worldwide development.Journal of Social and Development Sciences, 2, 111–120.

    Raynolds L T. 2002. Wages for wives: Renegotiating gender and production relations in contract farming in the Dominican Republic.World Development, 30, 783–798.

    Reardon T, Barrett C B. 2000. Agroindustrialization, globalization,and international development: An overview of issues,patterns, and determinants.Agricultural Economics, 23,195–205.

    Simmons P, Winters P, Patricka I. 2005. An analysis of contract farming in East Java, Bali, and Lombok, Indonesia.Agricultural Economics, 33, 513–525.

    Singh S. 2002. Contracting out solutions: Political economy of contract farming in the Indian Punjab.World Development,30, 1621–1638.

    Sivramkrishna S, Jyotishi A. 2008. Monopsonistic exploitation in contract farming: Articulating a strategy for grower cooperation.Journal of International Development, 20,280–296.

    Verhaegen I, Van Huylenbroeck G. 2001. Costs and benefits for farmers participating in innovative marketing channels for quality food products.Journal of Rural Studies, 17, 443–456.

    Welsh R. 2009. Farm and market structure, industrial regulation and rural community welfare: Conceptual and methodological issues.Agriculture and Human Values,26, 21–28.

    Wooldridge J M. 2015. Control function methods in applied econometrics.Journal of Human Resources, 50, 420–445.

    Xie C, Marchant M A. 2015. Supplying China’s growing appetite for poultry.International Food and Agribusiness Management Review, 18, 115–136.

    Xin X, Zhang Y, Wang J, Nuetah J A. 2016. Effects of farm size on technical efficiency in China’s broiler sector: A stochastic meta-frontier approach.Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 64, 493–516.

    Yang N, Jiang R S. 2005. Recent advances in breeding for quality chickens.World’s Poultry Science Journal, 61,373–381.

    猜你喜歡
    詞頻保護措施現(xiàn)行
    城市道路施工中地下管線保護措施
    沅江懷化段漁業(yè)資源增殖保護措施
    基于詞頻分析法的社區(qū)公園歸屬感營建要素研究
    園林科技(2021年3期)2022-01-19 03:17:48
    抓現(xiàn)行
    地面氣象觀測場防雷保護措施分析
    淺談我國現(xiàn)行的房產(chǎn)稅
    活力(2019年15期)2019-09-25 07:21:38
    被抓了現(xiàn)行
    現(xiàn)行企業(yè)內(nèi)部控制制度探討
    高山茶園如何做好防凍保護措施
    詞頻,一部隱秘的歷史
    成人毛片a级毛片在线播放| 精品熟女少妇av免费看| 99久久成人亚洲精品观看| 精品欧美国产一区二区三| 中文字幕熟女人妻在线| 亚洲成人中文字幕在线播放| 成人亚洲欧美一区二区av| 精品国内亚洲2022精品成人| 久久人人爽人人片av| 最近中文字幕高清免费大全6| 国产精品久久久久久精品电影| 亚洲欧美精品自产自拍| 欧美日本视频| 亚洲国产精品久久男人天堂| 99久久成人亚洲精品观看| 久久精品综合一区二区三区| 精品国产三级普通话版| 亚洲精品乱码久久久久久按摩| 欧美区成人在线视频| 观看免费一级毛片| 国产乱来视频区| 欧美xxxx性猛交bbbb| 国产在视频线精品| 日韩成人av中文字幕在线观看| 床上黄色一级片| 亚洲成人中文字幕在线播放| 国产极品天堂在线| 日本黄大片高清| 一个人看的www免费观看视频| 18+在线观看网站| 丝袜喷水一区| 中文字幕免费在线视频6| 干丝袜人妻中文字幕| 久久国内精品自在自线图片| 欧美色视频一区免费| 男人和女人高潮做爰伦理| 国产亚洲精品久久久com| 日韩欧美精品免费久久| 国产精品久久久久久av不卡| 国产精品精品国产色婷婷| 淫秽高清视频在线观看| 天堂√8在线中文| 国产高清视频在线观看网站| 国产精品国产三级国产av玫瑰| 国产不卡一卡二| 日本黄大片高清| 纵有疾风起免费观看全集完整版 | 国产成人福利小说| 久久精品久久久久久噜噜老黄 | 欧美三级亚洲精品| 男人和女人高潮做爰伦理| 国产黄片视频在线免费观看| 亚洲国产欧美人成| 久久精品夜夜夜夜夜久久蜜豆| 精品人妻视频免费看| 亚洲av中文av极速乱| 国产极品精品免费视频能看的| 九草在线视频观看| 看免费成人av毛片| 国产在线一区二区三区精 | 日本一本二区三区精品| 一级黄片播放器| av卡一久久| a级毛片免费高清观看在线播放| 午夜a级毛片| 午夜福利高清视频| 黄色一级大片看看| 一级毛片aaaaaa免费看小| 国产精品久久电影中文字幕| 能在线免费观看的黄片| 一区二区三区四区激情视频| 国产高清视频在线观看网站| 国产不卡一卡二| 又粗又爽又猛毛片免费看| 亚洲经典国产精华液单| 亚洲成色77777| 欧美日本视频| 免费一级毛片在线播放高清视频| 黄色欧美视频在线观看| 亚洲三级黄色毛片| 国产欧美日韩精品一区二区| a级一级毛片免费在线观看| 日韩一区二区视频免费看| 美女被艹到高潮喷水动态| 99热这里只有是精品50| 波多野结衣巨乳人妻| 国产探花在线观看一区二区| 久久久久久久久久久丰满| 国产精品伦人一区二区| 国产69精品久久久久777片| 最近的中文字幕免费完整| 日韩亚洲欧美综合| 亚洲婷婷狠狠爱综合网| 久久6这里有精品| 免费看美女性在线毛片视频| 色哟哟·www| 丰满人妻一区二区三区视频av| 欧美bdsm另类| 午夜a级毛片| 国产午夜精品久久久久久一区二区三区| 午夜福利高清视频| 寂寞人妻少妇视频99o| 国产成人精品久久久久久| 91午夜精品亚洲一区二区三区| 国产午夜精品一二区理论片| 亚洲欧美日韩东京热| 赤兔流量卡办理| av专区在线播放| 国产精品野战在线观看| 联通29元200g的流量卡| 成人美女网站在线观看视频| 直男gayav资源| 99久久成人亚洲精品观看| 国产日韩欧美在线精品| 又黄又爽又刺激的免费视频.| 精品人妻一区二区三区麻豆| 久久精品国产亚洲av天美| 亚洲国产精品国产精品| 午夜福利成人在线免费观看| 又爽又黄无遮挡网站| 日本三级黄在线观看| 秋霞伦理黄片| 国产免费男女视频| 美女脱内裤让男人舔精品视频| 久久精品91蜜桃| 国产极品天堂在线| 日韩精品有码人妻一区| 国产一区亚洲一区在线观看| 我要看日韩黄色一级片| 日韩av在线大香蕉| 精品欧美国产一区二区三| 精品无人区乱码1区二区| 亚洲精品456在线播放app| 美女高潮的动态| 乱码一卡2卡4卡精品| 久久精品熟女亚洲av麻豆精品 | 日韩 亚洲 欧美在线| 18禁动态无遮挡网站| videos熟女内射| 日韩在线高清观看一区二区三区| 伦理电影大哥的女人| 精品国产一区二区三区久久久樱花 | 亚洲国产高清在线一区二区三| 成人毛片a级毛片在线播放| 91aial.com中文字幕在线观看| 九九久久精品国产亚洲av麻豆| av免费在线看不卡| 亚洲国产欧美人成| 久久99热这里只频精品6学生 | 亚洲av电影不卡..在线观看| 国产免费又黄又爽又色| 国产在线男女| 看免费成人av毛片| 国产精品一区二区三区四区免费观看| 人妻夜夜爽99麻豆av| 日产精品乱码卡一卡2卡三| 日韩制服骚丝袜av| 久久久精品94久久精品| 欧美激情在线99| 精品一区二区三区视频在线| 美女高潮的动态| 精品人妻一区二区三区麻豆| 波多野结衣巨乳人妻| 国产精品一区二区在线观看99 | 国产精品一区www在线观看| 欧美性猛交╳xxx乱大交人| 日日摸夜夜添夜夜爱| 1024手机看黄色片| 韩国高清视频一区二区三区| 国产又黄又爽又无遮挡在线| 97超碰精品成人国产| 国产高清不卡午夜福利| 日韩av在线免费看完整版不卡| 深夜a级毛片| 国产成人免费观看mmmm| 亚洲最大成人av| 午夜亚洲福利在线播放| 午夜福利在线观看吧| 日韩亚洲欧美综合| 国产精品国产三级国产专区5o | 插逼视频在线观看| 婷婷色麻豆天堂久久 | 美女高潮的动态| 国产成人a区在线观看| 国产 一区精品| 在线免费观看的www视频| 欧美一区二区精品小视频在线| 22中文网久久字幕| 少妇丰满av| 国产高清国产精品国产三级 | 免费av毛片视频| 国产视频首页在线观看| 精品一区二区三区视频在线| 非洲黑人性xxxx精品又粗又长| 国产大屁股一区二区在线视频| 国产精品99久久久久久久久| 国产精品1区2区在线观看.| 成人毛片a级毛片在线播放| 国产三级在线视频| 禁无遮挡网站| 亚洲五月天丁香| 亚洲aⅴ乱码一区二区在线播放| 国产在视频线精品| 久久精品国产亚洲网站| 国产 一区 欧美 日韩| 色5月婷婷丁香| 成人综合一区亚洲| 观看免费一级毛片| 大香蕉久久网| 99视频精品全部免费 在线| 国产白丝娇喘喷水9色精品| 伊人久久精品亚洲午夜| 97超碰精品成人国产| 女人久久www免费人成看片 | 国内揄拍国产精品人妻在线| 亚洲精品乱久久久久久| 狂野欧美激情性xxxx在线观看| av视频在线观看入口| 国产精品嫩草影院av在线观看| 少妇熟女欧美另类| 免费黄网站久久成人精品| 免费观看精品视频网站| 91狼人影院| 亚洲成人av在线免费| 麻豆久久精品国产亚洲av| 自拍偷自拍亚洲精品老妇| 国产一区二区在线av高清观看| 色播亚洲综合网| 国产精品一区www在线观看| 国产又黄又爽又无遮挡在线| 精品酒店卫生间| 国产精品综合久久久久久久免费| 精品久久久久久久久亚洲| 在线免费观看的www视频| 欧美激情在线99| 高清毛片免费看| 国产乱人偷精品视频| 伦精品一区二区三区| 久久热精品热| 精品一区二区免费观看| 亚洲av电影在线观看一区二区三区 | 97热精品久久久久久| 国产中年淑女户外野战色| 久久人妻av系列| 国产精品.久久久| ponron亚洲| 精品一区二区免费观看| 一个人观看的视频www高清免费观看| 国产真实乱freesex| 亚洲久久久久久中文字幕| 欧美97在线视频| 全区人妻精品视频| 亚洲美女视频黄频| 亚洲av一区综合| 三级国产精品片| 丝袜喷水一区| 久久人妻av系列| 欧美另类亚洲清纯唯美| 少妇熟女欧美另类| 秋霞在线观看毛片| 成人鲁丝片一二三区免费| 久久久久久久国产电影| 少妇熟女欧美另类| 国产精品一区www在线观看| 午夜免费激情av| 91久久精品国产一区二区成人| 舔av片在线| 精品久久国产蜜桃| 免费av毛片视频| av播播在线观看一区| 日日啪夜夜撸| 欧美一区二区精品小视频在线| 日本-黄色视频高清免费观看| 欧美日韩国产亚洲二区| 成人高潮视频无遮挡免费网站| 国产欧美日韩精品一区二区| 高清毛片免费看| 成人亚洲精品av一区二区| 少妇人妻精品综合一区二区| 秋霞在线观看毛片| 亚洲三级黄色毛片| 午夜福利在线观看免费完整高清在| 久久精品国产自在天天线| 天美传媒精品一区二区| 中文字幕精品亚洲无线码一区| 中文字幕制服av| 美女被艹到高潮喷水动态| 国产精品.久久久| 亚洲精品aⅴ在线观看| 亚洲av男天堂| 国产亚洲最大av| 91精品国产九色| 日韩av不卡免费在线播放| 亚洲av免费在线观看| 卡戴珊不雅视频在线播放| 99热6这里只有精品| 亚洲精品乱码久久久v下载方式| 日本一本二区三区精品| av在线亚洲专区| 免费观看在线日韩| 婷婷色综合大香蕉| 亚洲av成人av| 91精品伊人久久大香线蕉| 精品人妻熟女av久视频| 国产免费又黄又爽又色| 亚洲中文字幕一区二区三区有码在线看| 久久精品夜夜夜夜夜久久蜜豆| 综合色av麻豆| 在现免费观看毛片| 国产亚洲av片在线观看秒播厂 | АⅤ资源中文在线天堂| 国产精品久久视频播放| 国产91av在线免费观看| 亚洲性久久影院| 久久99精品国语久久久| 午夜亚洲福利在线播放| 久久精品国产99精品国产亚洲性色| 嘟嘟电影网在线观看| 精品免费久久久久久久清纯| 日本三级黄在线观看| 欧美激情久久久久久爽电影| 精品人妻视频免费看| av视频在线观看入口| videos熟女内射| 永久网站在线| 精品午夜福利在线看| 麻豆av噜噜一区二区三区| h日本视频在线播放| 亚洲18禁久久av| 少妇熟女欧美另类| 国内精品一区二区在线观看| 国产精品一及| 国产精品久久久久久精品电影小说 | 午夜免费激情av| 麻豆乱淫一区二区| 哪个播放器可以免费观看大片| 天堂中文最新版在线下载 | 三级经典国产精品| 人妻夜夜爽99麻豆av| 婷婷六月久久综合丁香| 69人妻影院| 成年免费大片在线观看| 啦啦啦观看免费观看视频高清| 精品不卡国产一区二区三区| 精品人妻视频免费看| 九九热线精品视视频播放| 欧美成人a在线观看| 最近2019中文字幕mv第一页| 高清毛片免费看| 精品不卡国产一区二区三区| 日本猛色少妇xxxxx猛交久久| 极品教师在线视频| 大香蕉久久网| 中国美白少妇内射xxxbb| 国产精品熟女久久久久浪| 久久久精品大字幕| 99久久九九国产精品国产免费| 欧美bdsm另类| 一二三四中文在线观看免费高清| 国产v大片淫在线免费观看| 夫妻性生交免费视频一级片| 亚洲国产欧美在线一区| 麻豆av噜噜一区二区三区| 日本熟妇午夜| 亚洲怡红院男人天堂| 亚洲av电影在线观看一区二区三区 | 国产精品一区二区三区四区免费观看| 男女下面进入的视频免费午夜| 免费电影在线观看免费观看| 久久精品夜色国产| 亚洲经典国产精华液单| or卡值多少钱| 午夜精品国产一区二区电影 | 国产亚洲精品久久久com| 亚洲国产日韩欧美精品在线观看| 亚洲美女视频黄频| 国产淫片久久久久久久久| 美女被艹到高潮喷水动态| 99久久九九国产精品国产免费| 我的女老师完整版在线观看| 99热这里只有是精品在线观看| 国产精品99久久久久久久久| 美女黄网站色视频| 亚洲国产精品成人久久小说| 午夜视频国产福利| 性插视频无遮挡在线免费观看| 丝袜喷水一区| h日本视频在线播放| 国产精品一及| 水蜜桃什么品种好| 成人高潮视频无遮挡免费网站| av播播在线观看一区| 亚洲欧美日韩东京热| 国产av在哪里看| 欧美xxxx黑人xx丫x性爽| 天堂网av新在线| 日本五十路高清| 国模一区二区三区四区视频| 91精品一卡2卡3卡4卡| 亚洲自拍偷在线| 哪个播放器可以免费观看大片| 2021少妇久久久久久久久久久| 免费av观看视频| 亚洲国产精品sss在线观看| 看片在线看免费视频| 免费无遮挡裸体视频| 3wmmmm亚洲av在线观看| 一区二区三区乱码不卡18| 不卡视频在线观看欧美| 男女边吃奶边做爰视频| 亚洲精品一区蜜桃| 只有这里有精品99| 亚洲最大成人手机在线| 高清视频免费观看一区二区 | 永久免费av网站大全| 成人特级av手机在线观看| 国产精品久久视频播放| 国产亚洲精品av在线| 色吧在线观看| 久久精品国产99精品国产亚洲性色| 国产精品国产高清国产av| 色吧在线观看| 国产亚洲一区二区精品| 国产精品久久久久久久电影| 亚洲精品国产成人久久av| 久久久久久久亚洲中文字幕| 在线观看一区二区三区| 成人av在线播放网站| 亚洲中文字幕日韩| 中国国产av一级| av在线播放精品| 亚洲伊人久久精品综合 | 色视频www国产| 亚洲最大成人中文| 26uuu在线亚洲综合色| 91久久精品国产一区二区三区| 久久精品国产99精品国产亚洲性色| 日本黄大片高清| 欧美性猛交╳xxx乱大交人| 天堂影院成人在线观看| 蜜臀久久99精品久久宅男| 亚洲国产精品成人综合色| 欧美97在线视频| 2021天堂中文幕一二区在线观| 青青草视频在线视频观看| 免费黄网站久久成人精品| 久久欧美精品欧美久久欧美| 国产精品久久视频播放| 中文字幕av在线有码专区| 日韩欧美三级三区| 亚洲美女搞黄在线观看| 哪个播放器可以免费观看大片| 精品欧美国产一区二区三| 国产精品99久久久久久久久| 亚洲av福利一区| 久久久国产成人精品二区| 欧美日韩一区二区视频在线观看视频在线 | 日本黄大片高清| 日本av手机在线免费观看| 国产成人a区在线观看| 看非洲黑人一级黄片| 亚洲欧美日韩高清专用| 一级av片app| 特级一级黄色大片| 亚洲熟妇中文字幕五十中出| 婷婷色av中文字幕| 国产爱豆传媒在线观看| 亚洲国产最新在线播放| 高清视频免费观看一区二区 | 99在线人妻在线中文字幕| av线在线观看网站| 久久99蜜桃精品久久| 精品无人区乱码1区二区| 日本免费在线观看一区| 欧美成人a在线观看| 欧美高清成人免费视频www| 日韩大片免费观看网站 | av在线老鸭窝| 大话2 男鬼变身卡| 午夜福利在线观看吧| 伦精品一区二区三区| 午夜a级毛片| 狂野欧美白嫩少妇大欣赏| 国产老妇女一区| 亚洲精品国产成人久久av| 国产 一区 欧美 日韩| 汤姆久久久久久久影院中文字幕 | 亚洲av男天堂| 久久久国产成人精品二区| 波野结衣二区三区在线| 亚洲丝袜综合中文字幕| 色综合亚洲欧美另类图片| 国产v大片淫在线免费观看| ponron亚洲| 免费观看的影片在线观看| 久久精品国产亚洲av涩爱| 色哟哟·www| 直男gayav资源| 日韩中字成人| 特大巨黑吊av在线直播| 波多野结衣高清无吗| 亚洲欧美清纯卡通| 人妻制服诱惑在线中文字幕| 国产亚洲最大av| 高清毛片免费看| 国产精品1区2区在线观看.| 日本爱情动作片www.在线观看| 亚洲无线观看免费| 国产成人福利小说| 午夜精品一区二区三区免费看| 久久久久久伊人网av| 国产在线一区二区三区精 | 高清av免费在线| 日韩欧美国产在线观看| 婷婷色综合大香蕉| 麻豆av噜噜一区二区三区| 国产极品天堂在线| 秋霞在线观看毛片| 色视频www国产| 日本-黄色视频高清免费观看| 久久韩国三级中文字幕| 一个人看的www免费观看视频| 成人无遮挡网站| .国产精品久久| 综合色丁香网| 免费一级毛片在线播放高清视频| 少妇的逼好多水| 丝袜喷水一区| 亚洲av免费在线观看| 国产日韩欧美在线精品| 你懂的网址亚洲精品在线观看 | 国产亚洲最大av| 国产大屁股一区二区在线视频| 精品久久久久久电影网 | 91午夜精品亚洲一区二区三区| 国产淫片久久久久久久久| 天堂中文最新版在线下载 | 国产日韩欧美在线精品| 午夜精品一区二区三区免费看| 久久精品国产自在天天线| 麻豆av噜噜一区二区三区| 国产极品天堂在线| 麻豆av噜噜一区二区三区| 欧美+日韩+精品| 看十八女毛片水多多多| 我要搜黄色片| 少妇熟女aⅴ在线视频| 少妇裸体淫交视频免费看高清| 小蜜桃在线观看免费完整版高清| 亚洲av日韩在线播放| 丝袜美腿在线中文| 久久久久国产网址| 男女国产视频网站| 国产精品不卡视频一区二区| 国产精品精品国产色婷婷| 欧美潮喷喷水| 一边亲一边摸免费视频| 最近最新中文字幕大全电影3| 国产伦精品一区二区三区视频9| 国产亚洲av片在线观看秒播厂 | 波多野结衣巨乳人妻| 午夜a级毛片| 麻豆av噜噜一区二区三区| 日本五十路高清| 久久99热6这里只有精品| 汤姆久久久久久久影院中文字幕 | 国产精品无大码| 久久精品夜色国产| av福利片在线观看| 激情 狠狠 欧美| 国产成人午夜福利电影在线观看| 高清av免费在线| 精品久久久噜噜| 国产一区二区亚洲精品在线观看| 亚洲精华国产精华液的使用体验| 成年女人永久免费观看视频| a级一级毛片免费在线观看| 久久久精品欧美日韩精品| 99久久无色码亚洲精品果冻| 男人的好看免费观看在线视频| 国产午夜福利久久久久久| 精品欧美国产一区二区三| 22中文网久久字幕| 99热6这里只有精品| 国产精品无大码| 欧美3d第一页| 日韩中字成人| 99热这里只有精品一区| 久久精品人妻少妇| 能在线免费观看的黄片| 91久久精品电影网| 亚洲人与动物交配视频| 亚洲精品,欧美精品| 欧美成人午夜免费资源| 久久久久久久久久黄片| 国产大屁股一区二区在线视频| 国产欧美另类精品又又久久亚洲欧美| 联通29元200g的流量卡| 我要看日韩黄色一级片| 欧美激情国产日韩精品一区| 91久久精品国产一区二区成人| 精品不卡国产一区二区三区| 国产真实乱freesex| 国产亚洲5aaaaa淫片| 韩国高清视频一区二区三区| 97人妻精品一区二区三区麻豆| 中文字幕制服av| 国产成人91sexporn| 国产色婷婷99| 亚洲av一区综合| 精品不卡国产一区二区三区| 亚洲四区av| 亚洲中文字幕日韩| 国产亚洲精品久久久com| ponron亚洲|