• <tr id="yyy80"></tr>
  • <sup id="yyy80"></sup>
  • <tfoot id="yyy80"><noscript id="yyy80"></noscript></tfoot>
  • 99热精品在线国产_美女午夜性视频免费_国产精品国产高清国产av_av欧美777_自拍偷自拍亚洲精品老妇_亚洲熟女精品中文字幕_www日本黄色视频网_国产精品野战在线观看 ?

    One size fits all? Contract farming among broiler producers in China

    2018-02-05 07:11:00HUANGZeyingXUYingZENGDiWANGChenWANGJimin
    Journal of Integrative Agriculture 2018年2期
    關鍵詞:詞頻保護措施現(xiàn)行

    HUANG Ze-ying, XU Ying, ZENG Di, WANG Chen, WANG Ji-min

    1 Institute of Agricultural Economics and Development, Chinese Academy of Agricultural Sciences, Beijing 100081, P.R.China

    2 Centre for Global Food and Resources, University of Adelaide, Adelaide 5005, Australia

    1. lntroduction

    Agricultural contract can be generally defined as an agreement between producer and buyer which specifies the price of an agricultural commodity to be delivered at a certain point of time in the future (Harwoodet al. 1999). In the past decades, contract farming has observed increasing popularity in agrarian economies (Glover 1984; Nguyenet al. 2015). The expansion of contract farming is jointly triggered by increasing demand of agricultural products due to income and population growth, and increasing productivity given modern agricultural technologies in production, postharvest processing and distribution (Barrettet al. 2012).With potential benefits such as market assurance, input access for producers and risk mitigation for downstream contractors, contract farming is at the heart of agricultural value chain modernisation in developing countries (Glover 1990; Oya 2012; Martinez-Gomezet al. 2013).

    As most of the poor in developing countries are small agricultural producers, the welfare impacts of contract farming on smallholders have attracted growing attention in search of policy implications (Nguyenet al. 2015). Existing literature, however, provides only inconsistent findings.Political economy analyses tend to agree that smallholders have weak bargaining powervis-à-vismonopsonistic contractors, especially if they have few alternatives of livelihood (Grosh 1994; Little 1994). For this reason,smallholders might have seen little welfare improvement from contract farming (Merryet al. 2004; Sivramkrishna and Jyotishi 2008), and likely become quasi-employees as they yield to the downstream contractor in production decision making (Reardon and Barrett 2000). Moreover, contractors may favour larger producers while poorer growers could be marginalised (Little and Watts 1994; Singh 2002; Dev and Rao 2005). Negative externalities may further occur(Welsh 2009). While these critics seem appealing, a growing number of studies from a purely empirical perspective actually suggest the opposite: smallholders in developing countries do benefit from contract farming in terms of income (Bolwig and Gibbonet al. 2009; Miyataet al. 2009;Bellemare 2012), return to capital (Simmonset al. 2005),food security (Bellemare and Novak 2015), and women’s employment (Raynolds 2002). These conflicting results can hardly assist policy decisions aiming to improve welfare through contract farming, and more evidence is needed to build up external validity.

    Agricultural production in China has observed substantial changes in the past decades. The dietary structure has been shifting from plant-based to animal-based foods as a result of income growth (Fukase and Martin 2016), which is further magnified by population increase, yet the production behaviour in the poultry industry remains much unknown.In this article, we aim to narrow this knowledge gap through the investigation of contract farming participation of small broiler producers in China using a nationally representative survey. During the past decades, poultry industry in China has observed significant growth and has undergone rapid structural change from smallholder-dominated production to large-scale contract farming (Xie and Marchant 2015).Consequently, the poultry sector is no longer dominated by smallholders and many of them who used to keep broilers as a sideline activity have given up production (Ke and Han 2007). Remaining farmers generally specialise in broiler production (Xinet al. 2016). The welfare implications of broiler contract farming in China have not been formally analysed, though contract farming has grown rapidly in China (Guoet al. 2007), and empirical literature occasionally reports increased profitability for producers in neighbouring countries (Simmonset al. 2005; Narayanan 2014). The structural change and coexistence of small and large producers jointly provide a unique opportunity to analyse smallholder participation in contract farming and associated welfare results.

    We approach this topic from both descriptive and quantitative perspectives. We first summarise the characteristics of surveyed households as well as the market prices and costs in their broiler production, the latter of which suggests that contract farming might not be optimal for small producers through cost-benefit comparisons. We then proceed with the estimation of a multinomial logistic regression model to reveal how farmers’ choices among individual farming and three types of contract farming are associated with their socioeconomic characteristics, where the possible endogeneity of broiler production is corrected for using a control function approach. It is found that farm size significantly and consistently explains the variation in these choices. We finally discuss the implications of ourfindings, and conclude our analysis specifically with strategic suggestions for small broiler producers.

    2. Analytical framework

    While the contradictory welfare results in literature may be puzzling, a closer look reveals that contract farming usually leads to welfare improvements where most producers are smallholders (Simmonset al. 2005; Bolwig and Gibbon 2009; Miyataet al. 2009; Bellemare 2012; Bellemare and Novak 2015). This is intuitive because, if the market is mostly supplied by smallholders who face similar production costs, contracts would only occur if the contracted price is high enough to incentivise most smallholders to participate.However, when large holders are also existent, there could be some room for arbitrage for the downstream contractor,and smallholders would therefore lose. This is likely the case when the contracted price is large enough to attract large holders with their economies of scale and thus lower per unit production costs, but is not sufficient to offset the higher production costs faced by smallholders. Hence, the smallholder welfare impacts of contract farming may vary with the supply-side market structure.

    Fig. 1 depicts two different scenarios: with homogeneous producers (smallholders) and with heterogeneous producers (both small and large holders). In each graph,the upper block shows the cumulative percentage of total market production plotted against the cumulative percentage of the corresponding producers ranked by farm size from small to large, which is comparable to the Lorenz curve income distribution. The lower block,on the other hand, shows the average production cost among producers ranked in exactly the same manner.Therefore, with homogeneous producers, the cumulative production share curve is the 45-degree line and the average production cost is the same for all producers, as shown in Fig. 1-A. While with heterogeneous producers,the cumulative production share curve is below the 45-degree line as large holders produce disproportionally more than smallholders, and the average production cost is downward sloping given economies of scale that lowers the average cost when production increases. In both cases,for a certain among of production is to be delivered to the downstream contractor. With homogeneous producers,the contracted price is equal to the average production cost (a higher contracted price is not as profitable for the contractor while a lower contracted price generates a loss for farmers and thus may not be accepted). Producers ranked from b to c participate in contract farming in this case. With heterogeneous producers, however, only a small number of large producers participate in contract farming (from b to c), whose average production costs are below the contracted price, yet participation is not profitable for smaller producers ranked from a to b as their costs are higher than the contracted price. These smaller producers may therefore opt out of contract farming and look for alternative marketing opportunities to obtain higher profits.

    Although the above literature has intensively explored the welfare implications of contract farming in a variety of countries with almost homogeneous smallholders, less is known about possible impacts with the coexistence of small and large holders, and how expected profitability could affect the participation of smallholders in contract farming. This information, however, is needed to assist policy designs aimed at improving smallholder welfare and ensuring reasonable allocation of benefits associated with contract farming. With the simultaneous presence of heterogeneous farmers, the broiler industry in China is an ideal opportunity to analyse the smallholder welfare in this regard.

    Fig. 1 Contract farming with different supply-side market structures. A, contract farming with homogeneous producers (smallholders).B, contract farming with heterogeneous producers (small and large holders).

    3. Data and method

    The current study is facilitated by a recent national household survey of Chinese broiler producers implemented from June to August, 2015. Six provinces (autonomous region) are covered: Jilin, Hebei, Shandong, Hubei,Guangdong and Guangxi, which cover a wide spectrum of aggregate broiler production levels in the country and jointly represent 43% broiler meat production in China.The first three provinces are in northern China, while the latter three provinces (autonomous region) are in southern China. Stratified sampling strategy has been used for data collection. Within each stratum (province), four to five broiler-producing towns were randomly selected from a list of all broiler-producing towns provided by local agricultural experimental stations, and broiler producers were then randomly selected from producing household lists provided by the village committees. The survey was implemented through face-to-face interviews with farm household heads by the research team that consists of one professor and four doctoral students in the research field of poultry farm management. In our survey, 27 towns were selected with 15 farmers from each town, generating a sample frame of 405 broiler producers. Of these farmers, five refused to participate in the interviews, reducing the total sample to 400. However, in many cases the interviews were also interrupted mid-way through, or cancelled if the farmer was called away and an alternative time could not be identified. In the end, 373 questionnaires were conducted.367 questionnaires were finally deemed as complete with all information appropriately recorded, suggesting a valid response rate of 98.39%. These 367 producers thus serve as the full sample of our analysis.

    Three types of contracts are existent in our data: 1) firm contract, 2) cooperative contract, and 3) hybrid contract.Firm contract (firm+producer) is the most popular contract type, which occurs directly between the downstream processor (firm) and broiler producer. Cooperative contracts(cooperative+producer) are less common yet still existent in many areas, with the downstream contractor being the agricultural marketing cooperative rather than the firm.Unlike the firm, an agricultural marketing cooperative is an entity jointly owned and operated by producers, which pools their individual resources to facilitate final marketing.Hybrid contracts (firm+cooperative+producer) have also been observed in the last decade among Chinese broiler producers due to the beliefs that individual farmers can barely negotiate with large downstream contractors but agricultural cooperatives can generally represent farmers’economic interests. In a hybrid contract, the agricultural cooperative negotiates and contracts with the downstreamfirm on behalf of individual farmers who collectively operate the cooperative, while the agreement between the cooperative and individual farmers are pre-arranged.Therefore, the hybrid contract consists of two contracts,one between the cooperative and the firm, and the other between individual farmers and the cooperative. We further differentiate cooperative contract from hybrid contract by the market role of the cooperative. In the cooperative contract,the cooperative takes full responsibility of final-stage broiler marketing and directly deals with consumers (e.g., individual consumers, restaurants, school cafeterias); while in the hybrid contract, the cooperative does not participate in finalstage broiler marketing but contracts with a downstream business for further broiler processing.

    These contract types differ in strengths and weaknesses.While firm contract is perhaps the most straightforward type,it is often criticized as exploitive due to the weak bargaining power of individual producers (Grosh 1994; Little 1994).Cooperative contract, while voicing the needs of producers,can be inadvertently constrained by their lack of knowledge,skills, market information or appropriate business strategies.As a comparison, hybrid contract can help build a more stable relationship among producers and downstream agents as it both strengthens the collective bargaining power of producers and eases market information transmission back to producers given clear downstream needs, yet in reality it is more difficult to establish given the multiple parties involved and the difficulties of negotiation.

    In our survey, all the contracts were written and were signed before broiler production. Focus group study suggests farmers generally believe written contracts are better than oral ones in terms of securing the contracted marketing channel and clarifying terms and conditions(thereby facilitating easier conflict resolution in case of need). To create a contract, the downstream contractor first offers the written contract that specifies the quality, price, and production details including the time of transaction. Focus group study suggests product quality is a major incentive to use contracts, which accords with earlier literature (e.g.,Guoet al. 2007). Then negotiation occurs and the contract is signed when terms and conditions are agreed upon, and so the contracted price can vary among producers. In each contract type, the downstream contractor partly shares some of the responsibilities of broiler breed provision, technology training, consulting, and disease control practices, which results in looser contract structures as compared to vertical integration commonly observed in horticultural production.However, the contract relationship is reasonably stable as most farmers contract with the same downstream entity over the years given that the number of downstream contractors are limited in most localities. The nonparticipants of broiler production contracts always sold their broilers directly to the market in our data.

    Table 1 presents the summary statistics of the full samples and subsamples broken down by participation status of broiler contract farming and contract types.Household head characteristics, farm characteristics and broiler production practices are respectively presented in three panels. Among surveyed broiler producers, 59.4%(218 producers) participated in firm contract, whereas much fewer participated in either cooperative (46 producers)or hybrid (25 producers) contracts. The remaining 78 producers (21.3%) directly sold their broilers to the market without any contract engagement. While most household head and farm characteristics were very similar across these subsamples, firm contract participants did appear to be more likely female-headed and less likely Communist Party members, while hybrid contract participants were the most educated group with the lowest proportion of risk-averse producers. Nonparticipants of broiler contract farming looked rather alike, except that they possessed an above-average education level and there were fewer village cadres among them. Regarding farm characteristics, hybrid contract participants had the largest land area, which was about twice that of firm and cooperative contract participants and one third larger than that of nonparticipants. Moreover,nonparticipants were more likely to raise local broiler breeds and to be close to major markets. Most of these discrepancies, however, are small.

    More interesting patterns can be seen from a simple cost-benefit analysis of broiler production among surveyed farmers. Nonparticipants had the smallest annual production,which is about half that of the contract participants, which accords with earlier observations that contract farming might favour larger producers (Little and Watts 1994; Singh 2002; Dev and Rao 2005). On the other hand, the annual production of hybrid contract participants was the largest.Moreover, although hybrid contract participants realised the smallest profit per broiler, their total broiler income was still the highest among all subgroups given their largest annual production.

    A comparison among all subgroups further suggests that economies of scale are evident, as annual production and per broiler production cost rank in exactly reversed order.The average broiler weight at farm gate is the smallest for nonparticipants and their per broiler production cost is the highest, which could be partly due to the fact that there was no technological support from downstream contractors.However, the broiler prices they received directly from the market were substantially higher than those offered by contractors, and therefore the profit per broiler for nonparticipants (6.090 CNY or 0.968 USD in 2015) was averaged 327% that of all contract participants. As a result,even with the smallest annual production, the total broiler income of nonparticipants was not necessarily lower than(e.g., firm) contract participants. This is consistent with earlier findings (Verhaegen and Van Huylenbroeck 2001),and these observations imply that it might not be profitable for the former to participate in contract farming. To test this,we implement a simple counterfactual exercise by replacing the individual broiler market prices nonparticipants received with the province-level average contract price participants received. In that case, 74 out of 78 nonparticipants would have negative profits if they were participants, which confirms the above speculation.

    The above observation accords with our hypothesis that contract farming could have opposite welfare results between smaller and larger producers. To investigate the role of farm size in broiler contract farming participation,there is a need to further implement quantitative analysis where multiple factors are simultaneously controlled for. It is towards such analysis that we now turn.

    Table 1 Descriptive statistics of full samples and subsamples by contract type

    4. Results

    We employ multinomial logistic regression modelling to investigate the possible effect of farm size in broiler contract farming participation. Multinomial logistic regression is specifically useful in predicting the probabilities of mutually exclusive discrete choices with a set of independent variables (Greene 2012). In our case, the four discrete choices are firm contract participation, cooperative contract participation, hybrid contract participation and nonparticipation. Multinomial logistic regression is appropriate in our analysis because on one hand, a simple logistic regression with the binary outcome of participation/nonparticipation would not be capable to differentiate possible heterogeneity among choices over three contract types. On the other hand, contract participation decision and contract choice could not be separated as both were made before broiler production (or a nested logistic model would be more appropriate). Independent variables in our analysis include household head characteristics, farm characteristics and annual broiler production as described in Table 1. Broiler sales price, production cost and profit measures are not included as predictors because they were realised during or after the production process, and could not logically affect the participation decision or contract choice made before production. Neither included is broiler breed,which is usually provided by the downstream contractors if the producer participates in contract farming and is not a separate decision. However, annual production is included as it is the best available indicator of economies of scale, which might not change much during a single year.Finally, town dummies are included to capture any possible unobserved heterogeneity across localities.

    Empirical estimation of the multinomial logistic regression relies on the assumption of independence of irrelevant alternatives. It states that the odds, or relative probability, of preferring one choice over another are independent from the presence or absence of other alternatives, which therefore can be considered as “irrelevant”. We proceed with formal Hausman-type tests to see whether this assumption holds since the violation of which could invalidate our results, andfind that it does.

    現(xiàn)行國家評價體系中一級指標還有“保護措施”一項,用以評價保護措施的合理性、完善性和執(zhí)行力度。由于本文詞頻分析中出現(xiàn)的與保護管理相關的“管理、治理”二詞占比較低,故沒有將“保護措施”作為一級指標,而是在三級指標中出現(xiàn)。

    A potential concern of direct maximum likelihood estimation of the multinomial logistic model regards the possible endogeneity of annual broiler production, a decision made by the producer, which could result in biased and inconsistent estimates. Endogeneity has been recognized in contract choices in agricultural production (Ackerberg and Botticini 2002), yet addressing endogeneity in a multinomial logistic regression is technically very difficult (Wooldridge 2015). In our case, we employ the two-step control function estimation procedure proposed by Wooldridge (2015).In the first step, we estimate simple linear regression using an excluded instrument and covariates against the endogenous variable of annual broiler production, and obtain the residuals. In the second step, we then estimate a multinomial logistic model using the residual as the control function along with covariates. Standard errors are finally obtained using bootstrapping.

    The excluded instrument in our analysis is the area of broiler production facilities, which should intuitively affect annual broiler production but not affect broiler contract choice other than through annual production, thereby meeting the criteria of the instrumental variable. The pairwise correlation coefficient between the instrument and annual broiler production is 0.57, probably not as high as one may speculate, because 1) the different practices among producers lead to varying broiler densities during production,and 2) certain off-farm employment opportunities have prevented the broiler production facilities to reach their full capacities. In the first-step regression, the overallF-value is 41.76 (with aP-value of 0.000), suggesting the excluded instrument is reasonably strong.

    In the multinomial logistic regression, nonparticipation is set as the default outcome. Moreover, we should focus on the average partial effects of covariates to ease the interpretation of results. Table 2 presents the average partial effects obtained by estimating the average structural function (Wooldridge 2015). The overall model specification is statistically significant at the 1% level, suggesting all covariates together successfully explain part of the outcome variations.

    Among all covariates, annual production, which captures economies of scale, is statistically significant in all contract choices. This is in line with recent literature (Abebeet al.2016). Specifically, the probabilities of participating in firm,cooperative and hybrid contracts would be 0.010, 0.013 and 0.005 higher as annual production level increases by 1 000 broilers. While the average partial effects are small, the actual differences may not necessarily be. The interquartile range in annual production in our data is 30 000 broilers,which implies that the probabilities of participating in each type of contract can be 30, 39 and 15% higher for the median large producer (75% percentile of annual production–45 000 broilers) than for the median small producer (25%percentile of annual production –15 000 broilers). Thesefindings confirm our earlier observation that smallholders would be less likely to participate in broiler contract farming.

    Several patterns of the associations between other covariates and contract choices are also worth discussion.Being a village cadre encourages firm contract participation,while being a Communist Party member discourages it. In China, village cadres are usually experienced,entrepreneurial and more capable farmers who take the lead in economic activities, while Party members tend to be conservative individuals who are more likely to follow instructions of the local government. As very few producers were both village cadres and Party members in our data,these contradictory effects could simply reflect the conflicting roles of these engagements in this foremost contract type.While education does not seem to stimulate contract farming in general, better educated producers are less likely to participate in cooperative contract, where the cooperative is run by farmers and represent their economic interests.Moreover, risk-averse producers are found more likely to participate in either firm or cooperative contract, which is also intuitive given the more secure marketing channel with contract farming, though such association is not seen with hybrid contract participation. Most other covariates do not seem to be correlated with contract choices.

    Table 2 Multinomial logistic control function estimation of broiler contract choices (n=367)1)

    5. Discussion

    These findings further imply that it could be a rational choice for small producers to opt out of contract farming,which differs from the existing concern that they might be passively excluded from participation given that downstream contractors would prefer large producers (Little and Watts 1994; Singh 2002; Dev and Rao 2005). The underlying belief of the latter argument is that contract farming could potentially benefit all producers, and therefore nonparticipation would result in undesirable welfare loss for small producers,which is not the case in our study. Specifically, the poultry industry in China has been through rapid structural change where farmers increasingly specialise in broiler production,leading to the coexistence of small and large producers(Xie and Marchant 2015), which would largely explain the unprofitability of smaller producers in contract farming. This coexistence could be temporary and might fade over time given the progressive specialisation in broiler production and the fast increase of productivity among remaining broiler producers (Xinet al. 2016). However, our results are still of policy importance because, although broiler industry in China has been transitioning from smallholder-dominated production to large-scale contract farming, the ongoing process may take a long time and many small broiler producers are still expected to exist in the foreseeable future. Moreover, our data may also mirror the future market patterns of smallholder agriculture which is widely existent in agrarian economies and yet to be modernised. Hence,rather than contradicting recent literature that documents positive smallholder welfare impacts in those economies(e.g., Simmonset al. 2005; Bolwig and Gibbon 2009; Miyataet al. 2009; Bellemare 2012; Bellemare and Novak 2015),the current study complements it in terms of forecasting possible smallholder welfare scenarios that might occur as markets evolve.

    As contract farming may benefit smallholders only if they provide most of market supply, a key question is about the future of smallholders given the increasing prevalence of contract farming with agricultural modernisation.Expectedly, not all small producers would continue broiler production, increase productivity or participate in contract farming. While the welfare consequences of quitting broiler production are not necessarily undesirable, especially when outside opportunities are more profitable, possible impacts on remaining small producers still demand more attention.Specifically, as producers are price-driven, it is necessary to investigate how evolving market prices affect smallholder welfare.

    One interesting observation in our data is that the market prices received by nonparticipants of contract farming were much higher than the contracted prices for participants(Table 1). While middlemen’s profits might partly explain this difference, more can be revealed through a simple comparison of broiler breeds of nonparticipants. Among 76 nonparticipants, 33 produced broilers of improved breeds and 45 produced broilers of local breeds. The average price received by the former group (11.67 CNY, or 1.86 USD in 2015) is significantly lower than that of the latter group (19.28 CNY, or 3.07 USD in 2015,P-value through pairwiset-test: 0.003). This pattern, along with the fact that nonparticipants produce broilers of local breeds the most (Table 1), confirms earlier observation that Chinese consumers generally prefer “l(fā)ocal” chicken, which are free-range, slowly-growing with poor feed conversion, but with better meat quality in terms of flavour, tenderness,fat deposition, muscle fibre composition, as well as visual appearances (Yang and Jiang 2005). Therefore, consumers’willingness to pay for those “l(fā)ocal” chicken could be much higher. The implication of this consumer preference can be more profound when placed in the context regarding the future of small producers. A possible strategy is to meet these market needs by specialising in “l(fā)ocal” chicken or poultry products for which small producers possess a comparative advantage. This has already taken place in multiple food sectors. For example, organic food production has experienced an annual farmland increase of 8.9%between 2001 and 2011 to meet the increasing demand(Paull 2011). In the broiler industry, possible opportunities similarly exist for not only organic but also free-range chicken given their price privileges (Husaket al. 2008). Even in developed countries, the market opportunity for both organic and free range poultry products is yet to be fully developed(Castelliniet al. 2008). Specialising in these products could therefore be a possible long-term business strategy for small broiler producers given that contract farming is not profitable.

    6. Conclusion

    We investigate whether contract farming is a financially good option for small broiler producers using a recent nationally representative survey in China. In contrast with many recent studies, we find that contract farming does not benefit small producers in face of larger competitors, the latter of which assume lower production costs given their economies of scale. Descriptive and quantitative analyses further show that small producers were not disadvantageous in terms of socioeconomic characteristics. Certainly, low profits made them opt out of contract farming, given the much higher prices they received from directly selling to the market.Therefore, the current study complements recent empirical literature in extending the almost homogeneous supplyside market structure to cover the coexistence of small and large producers, and conclude that contract farming may not be able to effectively improve smallholder welfare in the latter case.

    We further discuss that small broiler producers may consider alternative opportunities to continue operating in the poultry industry, such as specialising in organic and free-range chicken, which better utilises their comparative advantages. Full cost-benefit analysis of these strategies,however, is beyond the scope of this study. Data limitations further exclude us from investigating the smallholder welfare dynamics of contract farming over time, especially with market structure evolvement from homogeneous small producers to the coexistence of small and large producers.As a first study on broiler contract farming in China, ourfindings only speak to this specific industry and more research is needed to establish external validity. These remaining issues are open for further investigation that could build on the current analysis to better derive policy implications regarding the welfare impacts of contract farming.

    Acknowledgements

    This study is supported by the earmarked fund for the Agricultural Science and Technology Innovation Program,Chinese Academy of Agricultural Sciences (ASTIPIAED-2017) and the Modern Agro-industry Technology Research System, the Ministry of Agriculture of China(CARS-42-G24). We thank Prof. Liu Chunfang, Dr. E Yuzhou and Miss Zhou Rui from Chinese Academy of Agricultural Sciences for their assistance in survey data collection and the supports of staffs from broilers test stations in Hebei,Jilin, Shandong, Guangxi, Hubei and Guangdong.

    Abebe G K, Bijman J, Royer A. 2016. Are middlemen facilitators or barriers to improve smallholders’ welfare in rural economies? Empirical evidence from Ethiopia.Journal of Rural Studies, 43, 203–213.

    Ackerberg D A, Botticini M. 2002. Endogenous matching and the empirical determinants of contract form.Journal of Political Economy, 110, 564–591.

    Barrett C B, Bachke M E, Bellemare M F, Michelson H C,Narayanan S, Walker T F. 2012. Smallholder participation in contract farming: Comparative evidence from five countries.World Development, 40, 715–730.

    Bellemare M F. 2012. As you sow, so shall you reap: The welfare impacts of contract farming.World Development,40, 1418–1434.

    Bellemare M F, Novak L. 2015. Contract farming and food security.American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 99,357–378.

    Bolwig S, Gibbon P. 2009. The economics of smallholder organic contract farming in tropical Africa.World Development, 37,1094–1104.

    Castellini C, Berri C, Le Bihan-Duval E, Martino G. 2008.Qualitative attributes and consumer perception of organic and free-range poultry meat.World’s Poultry Science Journal, 64, 500–512.

    Dev S M, Rao N C. 2005. Food processing and contract farming in Andhra Pradesh: A small farmer perspective.Economic and Political Weekly, 40, 2705–2713.

    Fukase E, Martin W. 2016. Who will feed China in the 21st century? Income growth and food demand and supply in China.Journal of Agricultural Economics, 67, 3–23.

    Glover D. 1990. Contract farming and outgrower schemes in east and southern Africa.Journal of Agricultural Economics,41,303–315.

    Glover D J. 1984. Contract farming and smallholder outgrower schemes in less developed countries.World Development,12, 1143–1157.

    Greene W H. 2012.Econometric Analysis. 7th ed. Prentice Hall,Upper Saddle River. pp. 763–766.

    Grosh B. 1994. Contract farming in Africa: An application of the new institutional economies.Journal of African Economics,3, 231–261.

    Guo H, Jolly R W, Zhu J. 2007. Contract farming in China:Perspectives of farm households and agribusiness firms.Comparative Economic Studies, 49, 285–312.

    Harwood J, Heifner R, Coble K, Perry J, Somwaru A. 1999.Managing Risk in Farming: Concepts, Research, and Analysis.Market and Trade Economics Division and Resource Economics Division, Economic Research Service,U.S. Department of Agriculture. Agricultural Economic Report No. 774.

    Husak R L, Sebranek J G, Bregendahl K. 2008. A survey of commercially available broilers marketed as organic, freerange, and conventional broilers for cooked meat yields,meat composition, and relative value.Poultry Science,87, 2367–2376.

    Ke B, Han Y. 2007. Poultry sector in China: Structural changes during the past decade and future trends. In: Thieme O,Pilling D, eds.,Poultry in the 21st Century: Avian Influenza and Beyond. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Bangkok, Rome, Italy. pp. 1–33.

    Little P. 1994. Contract farming and the development question.In: Little P, Watts M, eds.,Living Under Contract: Contract Farming and Agrarian Transformation in Sub-Saharan Africa. University of Wisconsin Press, Madison.

    Little P D, Watts M J. 1994.Living Under Contract: Contract Farming and Agrarian Transformation in the Sub-Saharan Africa. University of Wisconsin Press, Madison.

    Martinez-Gomez F, Aboites-Manrique G, Constance D H.2013. Neoliberal restructuring, neoregulation, and the Mexican poultry industry.Agriculture and Human Values,30, 495–510.

    Merry F D, Sheikh P A, Mcgrath D G. 2004. The role of informal contracts in the growth of small cattle herds on thefloodplains of the Lower Amazon.Agriculture and Human Values, 21, 377–386.

    Miyata S, Minot N, Hu D. 2009. Impact of contract farming on income: Linking small farmers, packers, and supermarkets in China.World Development, 37, 1781–1790.

    Narayanan S. 2014. Profits from participation in high value agriculture: Evidence of heterogeneous benefits in contract farming schemes in Southern India.Food Policy, 44,142–157.

    Nguyen A T, Dzator J, Nadolny A. 2015. Does contract farming improve productivity and income of farmers? A review of theory and evidence.Journal of Developing Areas, 49,531–538.

    Oya C. 2012. Contract farming in Sub-Saharan Africa: A survey of approaches, debates and issues.Journal of Agrarian Change, 12, 1–33.

    Paull J. 2011. The Uptake of organic agriculture: A decade of worldwide development.Journal of Social and Development Sciences, 2, 111–120.

    Raynolds L T. 2002. Wages for wives: Renegotiating gender and production relations in contract farming in the Dominican Republic.World Development, 30, 783–798.

    Reardon T, Barrett C B. 2000. Agroindustrialization, globalization,and international development: An overview of issues,patterns, and determinants.Agricultural Economics, 23,195–205.

    Simmons P, Winters P, Patricka I. 2005. An analysis of contract farming in East Java, Bali, and Lombok, Indonesia.Agricultural Economics, 33, 513–525.

    Singh S. 2002. Contracting out solutions: Political economy of contract farming in the Indian Punjab.World Development,30, 1621–1638.

    Sivramkrishna S, Jyotishi A. 2008. Monopsonistic exploitation in contract farming: Articulating a strategy for grower cooperation.Journal of International Development, 20,280–296.

    Verhaegen I, Van Huylenbroeck G. 2001. Costs and benefits for farmers participating in innovative marketing channels for quality food products.Journal of Rural Studies, 17, 443–456.

    Welsh R. 2009. Farm and market structure, industrial regulation and rural community welfare: Conceptual and methodological issues.Agriculture and Human Values,26, 21–28.

    Wooldridge J M. 2015. Control function methods in applied econometrics.Journal of Human Resources, 50, 420–445.

    Xie C, Marchant M A. 2015. Supplying China’s growing appetite for poultry.International Food and Agribusiness Management Review, 18, 115–136.

    Xin X, Zhang Y, Wang J, Nuetah J A. 2016. Effects of farm size on technical efficiency in China’s broiler sector: A stochastic meta-frontier approach.Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 64, 493–516.

    Yang N, Jiang R S. 2005. Recent advances in breeding for quality chickens.World’s Poultry Science Journal, 61,373–381.

    猜你喜歡
    詞頻保護措施現(xiàn)行
    城市道路施工中地下管線保護措施
    沅江懷化段漁業(yè)資源增殖保護措施
    基于詞頻分析法的社區(qū)公園歸屬感營建要素研究
    園林科技(2021年3期)2022-01-19 03:17:48
    抓現(xiàn)行
    地面氣象觀測場防雷保護措施分析
    淺談我國現(xiàn)行的房產(chǎn)稅
    活力(2019年15期)2019-09-25 07:21:38
    被抓了現(xiàn)行
    現(xiàn)行企業(yè)內(nèi)部控制制度探討
    高山茶園如何做好防凍保護措施
    詞頻,一部隱秘的歷史
    1024香蕉在线观看| 国产成人系列免费观看| 国产精品久久久久久精品电影 | 91精品三级在线观看| 亚洲人成77777在线视频| 亚洲精华国产精华精| 亚洲av第一区精品v没综合| 亚洲熟妇熟女久久| 成人国产一区最新在线观看| 女性被躁到高潮视频| 热re99久久国产66热| 精品卡一卡二卡四卡免费| 亚洲精品中文字幕在线视频| 男女床上黄色一级片免费看| 久久久久九九精品影院| 日本在线视频免费播放| 亚洲专区字幕在线| 久久香蕉精品热| 亚洲中文字幕一区二区三区有码在线看 | 纯流量卡能插随身wifi吗| 午夜福利影视在线免费观看| 在线视频色国产色| 日本免费a在线| 18禁黄网站禁片午夜丰满| 正在播放国产对白刺激| 国产1区2区3区精品| 精品一区二区三区av网在线观看| 1024视频免费在线观看| 国产一区二区在线av高清观看| 一区二区日韩欧美中文字幕| 99re在线观看精品视频| 18禁美女被吸乳视频| 日本撒尿小便嘘嘘汇集6| 可以在线观看毛片的网站| 精品国产超薄肉色丝袜足j| 人人妻,人人澡人人爽秒播| 99国产极品粉嫩在线观看| 久久欧美精品欧美久久欧美| 两个人看的免费小视频| 99久久综合精品五月天人人| 亚洲avbb在线观看| 国产av一区在线观看免费| 岛国在线观看网站| 亚洲精品一区av在线观看| 久久香蕉国产精品| 国产麻豆成人av免费视频| 看免费av毛片| 欧美日韩瑟瑟在线播放| 国产成+人综合+亚洲专区| 美国免费a级毛片| 成人18禁在线播放| 老鸭窝网址在线观看| 国产一区在线观看成人免费| 老司机在亚洲福利影院| 黑人操中国人逼视频| 日日夜夜操网爽| 色综合婷婷激情| 少妇 在线观看| 欧美黑人精品巨大| 久久久水蜜桃国产精品网| 黄色视频不卡| 99国产精品免费福利视频| 好男人电影高清在线观看| 757午夜福利合集在线观看| 黄色毛片三级朝国网站| 亚洲欧美激情综合另类| 国产成人av激情在线播放| 成人欧美大片| 变态另类成人亚洲欧美熟女 | 一级片免费观看大全| 亚洲av成人av| 村上凉子中文字幕在线| 美女免费视频网站| 免费在线观看影片大全网站| 欧美精品亚洲一区二区| 欧美精品亚洲一区二区| 999精品在线视频| 亚洲成av片中文字幕在线观看| 国产精品久久视频播放| 亚洲国产精品久久男人天堂| 亚洲精品av麻豆狂野| 香蕉久久夜色| svipshipincom国产片| 成年人黄色毛片网站| 久久久久九九精品影院| 桃色一区二区三区在线观看| 精品卡一卡二卡四卡免费| 女人高潮潮喷娇喘18禁视频| 亚洲av熟女| 成人国语在线视频| 一边摸一边抽搐一进一出视频| 男人舔女人下体高潮全视频| 久久精品影院6| 亚洲一码二码三码区别大吗| 日韩高清综合在线| 露出奶头的视频| 亚洲精品美女久久久久99蜜臀| 久久久国产欧美日韩av| 午夜影院日韩av| 精品人妻1区二区| 色哟哟哟哟哟哟| 丝袜在线中文字幕| 宅男免费午夜| 69av精品久久久久久| av网站免费在线观看视频| 久久久久九九精品影院| 日本 欧美在线| 国产成人精品无人区| 91av网站免费观看| 亚洲五月婷婷丁香| 亚洲欧洲精品一区二区精品久久久| 变态另类成人亚洲欧美熟女 | 亚洲精品国产色婷婷电影| 国产乱人伦免费视频| 国产男靠女视频免费网站| 国产91精品成人一区二区三区| 美女免费视频网站| 日韩 欧美 亚洲 中文字幕| 亚洲专区中文字幕在线| 日本五十路高清| 亚洲国产毛片av蜜桃av| 男人舔女人的私密视频| 国产精品影院久久| 亚洲人成77777在线视频| 精品久久蜜臀av无| 亚洲国产高清在线一区二区三 | 欧美黄色片欧美黄色片| 精品一区二区三区四区五区乱码| 淫妇啪啪啪对白视频| 亚洲av成人一区二区三| 在线观看66精品国产| 欧美不卡视频在线免费观看 | av有码第一页| 亚洲精品中文字幕一二三四区| 国产一区二区激情短视频| 色综合站精品国产| 一进一出抽搐动态| 久久影院123| a级毛片在线看网站| 久久中文看片网| 亚洲欧美日韩无卡精品| 国产免费av片在线观看野外av| 美女高潮喷水抽搐中文字幕| 日韩欧美一区二区三区在线观看| 天天一区二区日本电影三级 | 涩涩av久久男人的天堂| 日本 av在线| 村上凉子中文字幕在线| 老汉色av国产亚洲站长工具| 天天添夜夜摸| 90打野战视频偷拍视频| 亚洲国产欧美一区二区综合| 午夜精品在线福利| 中文字幕人妻丝袜一区二区| 国产av精品麻豆| 国产成人欧美在线观看| 成人特级黄色片久久久久久久| 久久精品影院6| 夜夜夜夜夜久久久久| 欧美 亚洲 国产 日韩一| www.自偷自拍.com| 男女下面进入的视频免费午夜 | 亚洲一区高清亚洲精品| 欧美黄色淫秽网站| 亚洲 欧美一区二区三区| 亚洲一区高清亚洲精品| 亚洲男人的天堂狠狠| 中出人妻视频一区二区| 午夜老司机福利片| 亚洲欧美精品综合久久99| 91在线观看av| 波多野结衣高清无吗| 人成视频在线观看免费观看| 丝袜美足系列| 免费av毛片视频| 男人操女人黄网站| 国产精品一区二区在线不卡| 欧美乱码精品一区二区三区| 麻豆一二三区av精品| 真人做人爱边吃奶动态| 黄片播放在线免费| 搞女人的毛片| 侵犯人妻中文字幕一二三四区| 一级黄色大片毛片| 少妇粗大呻吟视频| 色在线成人网| 国产成人影院久久av| 亚洲精品av麻豆狂野| 啦啦啦免费观看视频1| 这个男人来自地球电影免费观看| 99久久99久久久精品蜜桃| 日本 av在线| 午夜精品久久久久久毛片777| 50天的宝宝边吃奶边哭怎么回事| 成人国产综合亚洲| 韩国精品一区二区三区| 日韩精品青青久久久久久| 少妇 在线观看| 嫩草影视91久久| 亚洲国产精品999在线| 国产黄a三级三级三级人| 亚洲第一欧美日韩一区二区三区| 亚洲中文字幕一区二区三区有码在线看 | 午夜精品久久久久久毛片777| 亚洲va日本ⅴa欧美va伊人久久| 91成人精品电影| 制服丝袜大香蕉在线| 亚洲人成电影免费在线| 老司机午夜十八禁免费视频| av网站免费在线观看视频| 亚洲精品久久国产高清桃花| 亚洲色图 男人天堂 中文字幕| √禁漫天堂资源中文www| 国产午夜福利久久久久久| 欧美日韩亚洲综合一区二区三区_| 国内久久婷婷六月综合欲色啪| 午夜视频精品福利| a级毛片在线看网站| 看免费av毛片| 色哟哟哟哟哟哟| 亚洲第一青青草原| 亚洲性夜色夜夜综合| АⅤ资源中文在线天堂| 他把我摸到了高潮在线观看| а√天堂www在线а√下载| 欧美在线一区亚洲| 久99久视频精品免费| 精品午夜福利视频在线观看一区| 50天的宝宝边吃奶边哭怎么回事| 亚洲精品一区av在线观看| 视频在线观看一区二区三区| 免费在线观看视频国产中文字幕亚洲| 宅男免费午夜| 禁无遮挡网站| 天堂影院成人在线观看| 99国产精品一区二区三区| 免费在线观看视频国产中文字幕亚洲| 欧美日韩精品网址| 久久精品91蜜桃| 两个人免费观看高清视频| 最近最新中文字幕大全免费视频| 久久 成人 亚洲| 欧美黑人精品巨大| 老司机午夜福利在线观看视频| 丝袜在线中文字幕| 黄片大片在线免费观看| 一本大道久久a久久精品| 村上凉子中文字幕在线| 国内毛片毛片毛片毛片毛片| 18禁黄网站禁片午夜丰满| 精品日产1卡2卡| 国产在线精品亚洲第一网站| 少妇熟女aⅴ在线视频| 亚洲国产精品999在线| 国产亚洲精品久久久久5区| 91大片在线观看| 村上凉子中文字幕在线| 一级作爱视频免费观看| 亚洲色图av天堂| 黑丝袜美女国产一区| 日韩欧美国产在线观看| 12—13女人毛片做爰片一| 亚洲,欧美精品.| 欧美成人一区二区免费高清观看 | 嫩草影院精品99| 嫩草影院精品99| 51午夜福利影视在线观看| 亚洲五月婷婷丁香| 午夜久久久久精精品| 亚洲人成网站在线播放欧美日韩| 国产99白浆流出| 99国产精品一区二区蜜桃av| 亚洲在线自拍视频| av天堂在线播放| 长腿黑丝高跟| 操出白浆在线播放| 一级毛片高清免费大全| 97碰自拍视频| 久久中文字幕人妻熟女| 久久精品91无色码中文字幕| 午夜老司机福利片| 自拍欧美九色日韩亚洲蝌蚪91| 脱女人内裤的视频| 嫩草影视91久久| 亚洲精品久久成人aⅴ小说| 日韩三级视频一区二区三区| 久久九九热精品免费| 伦理电影免费视频| 精品一区二区三区视频在线观看免费| 欧美老熟妇乱子伦牲交| 老司机午夜福利在线观看视频| 天天躁夜夜躁狠狠躁躁| 又大又爽又粗| 国产成人免费无遮挡视频| 亚洲精品在线观看二区| 视频区欧美日本亚洲| 欧美日韩乱码在线| 日本 av在线| 国产精品电影一区二区三区| 在线观看66精品国产| 午夜免费观看网址| 午夜福利,免费看| 视频在线观看一区二区三区| 国产片内射在线| 亚洲国产高清在线一区二区三 | 伦理电影免费视频| 亚洲一区二区三区色噜噜| 久久香蕉国产精品| 免费在线观看日本一区| www.999成人在线观看| 老司机福利观看| 欧美亚洲日本最大视频资源| 一二三四社区在线视频社区8| 久久久国产成人免费| 怎么达到女性高潮| 亚洲熟女毛片儿| 欧美在线黄色| 免费人成视频x8x8入口观看| 一区在线观看完整版| 黑人欧美特级aaaaaa片| 亚洲中文字幕一区二区三区有码在线看 | 久久精品成人免费网站| 欧美日韩精品网址| 国产一区二区在线av高清观看| 无人区码免费观看不卡| 一级毛片高清免费大全| 亚洲国产高清在线一区二区三 | 国产成人免费无遮挡视频| 一区二区三区激情视频| 国产av在哪里看| 黄频高清免费视频| 欧美丝袜亚洲另类 | 国产免费av片在线观看野外av| 国产亚洲av嫩草精品影院| 亚洲 欧美一区二区三区| 一区二区三区激情视频| 女人高潮潮喷娇喘18禁视频| 日本精品一区二区三区蜜桃| 在线观看免费日韩欧美大片| 日韩大尺度精品在线看网址 | 亚洲中文av在线| 在线观看免费日韩欧美大片| 免费观看精品视频网站| 亚洲成人精品中文字幕电影| 操美女的视频在线观看| 乱人伦中国视频| 日韩大码丰满熟妇| 丝袜美足系列| 国产成人系列免费观看| 制服诱惑二区| 50天的宝宝边吃奶边哭怎么回事| 国产亚洲精品一区二区www| 亚洲全国av大片| 91麻豆精品激情在线观看国产| 90打野战视频偷拍视频| 国产区一区二久久| 欧美乱码精品一区二区三区| 丁香欧美五月| 亚洲精品中文字幕一二三四区| av天堂久久9| av中文乱码字幕在线| 91国产中文字幕| 咕卡用的链子| 国产又色又爽无遮挡免费看| 国产亚洲av嫩草精品影院| 看片在线看免费视频| 亚洲精品国产区一区二| 国产91精品成人一区二区三区| 人成视频在线观看免费观看| 精品久久久久久成人av| 变态另类成人亚洲欧美熟女 | 在线观看日韩欧美| www日本在线高清视频| 欧美激情 高清一区二区三区| 天堂影院成人在线观看| 99国产精品免费福利视频| 日韩欧美国产在线观看| 亚洲国产毛片av蜜桃av| 麻豆国产av国片精品| 中文字幕精品免费在线观看视频| 不卡一级毛片| 一个人免费在线观看的高清视频| 99香蕉大伊视频| 一级毛片高清免费大全| 久热这里只有精品99| 在线观看免费日韩欧美大片| avwww免费| 亚洲五月天丁香| 看片在线看免费视频| 色综合亚洲欧美另类图片| 黄色丝袜av网址大全| 1024香蕉在线观看| 人妻丰满熟妇av一区二区三区| 亚洲熟妇熟女久久| 国产亚洲精品av在线| 成在线人永久免费视频| 在线十欧美十亚洲十日本专区| 91av网站免费观看| 757午夜福利合集在线观看| а√天堂www在线а√下载| 亚洲中文日韩欧美视频| 久久天堂一区二区三区四区| 老司机午夜十八禁免费视频| 夜夜看夜夜爽夜夜摸| 18禁国产床啪视频网站| 欧美人与性动交α欧美精品济南到| 欧美中文综合在线视频| 欧美一区二区精品小视频在线| av网站免费在线观看视频| 91大片在线观看| 国产av在哪里看| 国产亚洲av嫩草精品影院| 精品高清国产在线一区| 免费av毛片视频| 国内精品久久久久久久电影| 韩国精品一区二区三区| 女人被狂操c到高潮| 国产成人系列免费观看| 精品无人区乱码1区二区| 亚洲人成网站在线播放欧美日韩| 国内毛片毛片毛片毛片毛片| 中文字幕久久专区| 国产xxxxx性猛交| 日韩大码丰满熟妇| 久久国产亚洲av麻豆专区| 精品国产美女av久久久久小说| 日本a在线网址| 最近最新中文字幕大全电影3 | 老司机午夜十八禁免费视频| 成年版毛片免费区| 亚洲av电影在线进入| 91大片在线观看| 在线观看一区二区三区| 九色国产91popny在线| 午夜福利一区二区在线看| 欧美一级毛片孕妇| 韩国精品一区二区三区| 亚洲中文av在线| 欧美成人一区二区免费高清观看 | 久久午夜亚洲精品久久| 麻豆一二三区av精品| 啦啦啦免费观看视频1| 国产精品美女特级片免费视频播放器 | 搡老熟女国产l中国老女人| 性色av乱码一区二区三区2| 成人国产综合亚洲| 两性夫妻黄色片| 国产精品香港三级国产av潘金莲| 久久久久九九精品影院| 制服丝袜大香蕉在线| 国产伦人伦偷精品视频| 亚洲av五月六月丁香网| 欧美乱妇无乱码| 国产亚洲精品久久久久久毛片| 桃红色精品国产亚洲av| 国产成人欧美| 色播亚洲综合网| 在线国产一区二区在线| 啦啦啦免费观看视频1| 国产欧美日韩综合在线一区二区| 在线十欧美十亚洲十日本专区| 大型黄色视频在线免费观看| 久久精品人人爽人人爽视色| 国产成人av教育| 在线十欧美十亚洲十日本专区| 日韩精品免费视频一区二区三区| 如日韩欧美国产精品一区二区三区| 亚洲欧美精品综合久久99| 欧美国产精品va在线观看不卡| 国产在线观看jvid| 美女扒开内裤让男人捅视频| 88av欧美| 精品久久久久久久人妻蜜臀av | 91成年电影在线观看| 最新美女视频免费是黄的| 欧美+亚洲+日韩+国产| 国产黄a三级三级三级人| 久久久久国内视频| 99国产精品99久久久久| 久久欧美精品欧美久久欧美| АⅤ资源中文在线天堂| 老司机午夜十八禁免费视频| 身体一侧抽搐| 久久久精品欧美日韩精品| 啦啦啦韩国在线观看视频| 国产三级在线视频| 精品日产1卡2卡| 美女午夜性视频免费| 国产av一区在线观看免费| 日韩欧美三级三区| 黄色片一级片一级黄色片| 老熟妇乱子伦视频在线观看| 少妇裸体淫交视频免费看高清 | 大码成人一级视频| 午夜两性在线视频| 日本免费a在线| 免费在线观看日本一区| 97碰自拍视频| 亚洲一码二码三码区别大吗| 国产精品一区二区在线不卡| 人人妻,人人澡人人爽秒播| 又大又爽又粗| 欧美绝顶高潮抽搐喷水| 国产精品 国内视频| 免费无遮挡裸体视频| 久久人妻福利社区极品人妻图片| 国产人伦9x9x在线观看| av免费在线观看网站| 日日干狠狠操夜夜爽| 亚洲午夜理论影院| 日韩欧美三级三区| 性欧美人与动物交配| 久久久久久免费高清国产稀缺| 男女下面插进去视频免费观看| 9191精品国产免费久久| ponron亚洲| 麻豆av在线久日| 免费一级毛片在线播放高清视频 | 国产亚洲精品久久久久5区| 免费久久久久久久精品成人欧美视频| 99re在线观看精品视频| 9色porny在线观看| 精品久久久久久久毛片微露脸| 精品高清国产在线一区| 亚洲熟妇熟女久久| 午夜久久久久精精品| 国产又爽黄色视频| 男人操女人黄网站| 好看av亚洲va欧美ⅴa在| 无遮挡黄片免费观看| 黄片大片在线免费观看| 成年版毛片免费区| 18禁美女被吸乳视频| 亚洲avbb在线观看| 亚洲自拍偷在线| 精品无人区乱码1区二区| 欧美不卡视频在线免费观看 | 高清在线国产一区| 19禁男女啪啪无遮挡网站| 一本大道久久a久久精品| 99国产精品一区二区蜜桃av| 女性被躁到高潮视频| 老汉色av国产亚洲站长工具| 亚洲国产精品久久男人天堂| 村上凉子中文字幕在线| 欧美乱妇无乱码| 国产亚洲精品综合一区在线观看 | 中亚洲国语对白在线视频| 中文字幕久久专区| 巨乳人妻的诱惑在线观看| 69精品国产乱码久久久| 超碰成人久久| 叶爱在线成人免费视频播放| 国产精品亚洲美女久久久| 夜夜爽天天搞| 欧美一区二区精品小视频在线| 中文字幕色久视频| 亚洲av美国av| 国产av一区在线观看免费| 精品人妻在线不人妻| 校园春色视频在线观看| 日韩 欧美 亚洲 中文字幕| 99精品久久久久人妻精品| 黄网站色视频无遮挡免费观看| 男女之事视频高清在线观看| av电影中文网址| 女生性感内裤真人,穿戴方法视频| 多毛熟女@视频| 欧美av亚洲av综合av国产av| 制服诱惑二区| 精品福利观看| 一个人观看的视频www高清免费观看 | 中文字幕最新亚洲高清| 午夜a级毛片| 天堂影院成人在线观看| 国产精品99久久99久久久不卡| 女性生殖器流出的白浆| 夜夜躁狠狠躁天天躁| 99在线人妻在线中文字幕| 精品国内亚洲2022精品成人| 一级a爱片免费观看的视频| 日本vs欧美在线观看视频| 欧美+亚洲+日韩+国产| 精品无人区乱码1区二区| 97人妻精品一区二区三区麻豆 | 久久人妻熟女aⅴ| 亚洲欧美精品综合一区二区三区| 性少妇av在线| 中文字幕人成人乱码亚洲影| 国产精品一区二区在线不卡| 亚洲精品粉嫩美女一区| 真人做人爱边吃奶动态| 精品国产乱码久久久久久男人| 欧美中文日本在线观看视频| 巨乳人妻的诱惑在线观看| 欧美黄色淫秽网站| 神马国产精品三级电影在线观看 | av天堂久久9| 亚洲,欧美精品.| 国内久久婷婷六月综合欲色啪| av天堂在线播放| 精品国产一区二区久久| 色在线成人网| 久久伊人香网站| 久久精品国产清高在天天线| 国内精品久久久久精免费| 亚洲成av片中文字幕在线观看| 亚洲在线自拍视频| 婷婷六月久久综合丁香| 91麻豆av在线| 一a级毛片在线观看| 精品久久久久久成人av| 他把我摸到了高潮在线观看| 最新美女视频免费是黄的| av在线播放免费不卡|