• <tr id="yyy80"></tr>
  • <sup id="yyy80"></sup>
  • <tfoot id="yyy80"><noscript id="yyy80"></noscript></tfoot>
  • 99热精品在线国产_美女午夜性视频免费_国产精品国产高清国产av_av欧美777_自拍偷自拍亚洲精品老妇_亚洲熟女精品中文字幕_www日本黄色视频网_国产精品野战在线观看 ?

    One size fits all? Contract farming among broiler producers in China

    2018-02-05 07:11:00HUANGZeyingXUYingZENGDiWANGChenWANGJimin
    Journal of Integrative Agriculture 2018年2期
    關鍵詞:詞頻保護措施現(xiàn)行

    HUANG Ze-ying, XU Ying, ZENG Di, WANG Chen, WANG Ji-min

    1 Institute of Agricultural Economics and Development, Chinese Academy of Agricultural Sciences, Beijing 100081, P.R.China

    2 Centre for Global Food and Resources, University of Adelaide, Adelaide 5005, Australia

    1. lntroduction

    Agricultural contract can be generally defined as an agreement between producer and buyer which specifies the price of an agricultural commodity to be delivered at a certain point of time in the future (Harwoodet al. 1999). In the past decades, contract farming has observed increasing popularity in agrarian economies (Glover 1984; Nguyenet al. 2015). The expansion of contract farming is jointly triggered by increasing demand of agricultural products due to income and population growth, and increasing productivity given modern agricultural technologies in production, postharvest processing and distribution (Barrettet al. 2012).With potential benefits such as market assurance, input access for producers and risk mitigation for downstream contractors, contract farming is at the heart of agricultural value chain modernisation in developing countries (Glover 1990; Oya 2012; Martinez-Gomezet al. 2013).

    As most of the poor in developing countries are small agricultural producers, the welfare impacts of contract farming on smallholders have attracted growing attention in search of policy implications (Nguyenet al. 2015). Existing literature, however, provides only inconsistent findings.Political economy analyses tend to agree that smallholders have weak bargaining powervis-à-vismonopsonistic contractors, especially if they have few alternatives of livelihood (Grosh 1994; Little 1994). For this reason,smallholders might have seen little welfare improvement from contract farming (Merryet al. 2004; Sivramkrishna and Jyotishi 2008), and likely become quasi-employees as they yield to the downstream contractor in production decision making (Reardon and Barrett 2000). Moreover, contractors may favour larger producers while poorer growers could be marginalised (Little and Watts 1994; Singh 2002; Dev and Rao 2005). Negative externalities may further occur(Welsh 2009). While these critics seem appealing, a growing number of studies from a purely empirical perspective actually suggest the opposite: smallholders in developing countries do benefit from contract farming in terms of income (Bolwig and Gibbonet al. 2009; Miyataet al. 2009;Bellemare 2012), return to capital (Simmonset al. 2005),food security (Bellemare and Novak 2015), and women’s employment (Raynolds 2002). These conflicting results can hardly assist policy decisions aiming to improve welfare through contract farming, and more evidence is needed to build up external validity.

    Agricultural production in China has observed substantial changes in the past decades. The dietary structure has been shifting from plant-based to animal-based foods as a result of income growth (Fukase and Martin 2016), which is further magnified by population increase, yet the production behaviour in the poultry industry remains much unknown.In this article, we aim to narrow this knowledge gap through the investigation of contract farming participation of small broiler producers in China using a nationally representative survey. During the past decades, poultry industry in China has observed significant growth and has undergone rapid structural change from smallholder-dominated production to large-scale contract farming (Xie and Marchant 2015).Consequently, the poultry sector is no longer dominated by smallholders and many of them who used to keep broilers as a sideline activity have given up production (Ke and Han 2007). Remaining farmers generally specialise in broiler production (Xinet al. 2016). The welfare implications of broiler contract farming in China have not been formally analysed, though contract farming has grown rapidly in China (Guoet al. 2007), and empirical literature occasionally reports increased profitability for producers in neighbouring countries (Simmonset al. 2005; Narayanan 2014). The structural change and coexistence of small and large producers jointly provide a unique opportunity to analyse smallholder participation in contract farming and associated welfare results.

    We approach this topic from both descriptive and quantitative perspectives. We first summarise the characteristics of surveyed households as well as the market prices and costs in their broiler production, the latter of which suggests that contract farming might not be optimal for small producers through cost-benefit comparisons. We then proceed with the estimation of a multinomial logistic regression model to reveal how farmers’ choices among individual farming and three types of contract farming are associated with their socioeconomic characteristics, where the possible endogeneity of broiler production is corrected for using a control function approach. It is found that farm size significantly and consistently explains the variation in these choices. We finally discuss the implications of ourfindings, and conclude our analysis specifically with strategic suggestions for small broiler producers.

    2. Analytical framework

    While the contradictory welfare results in literature may be puzzling, a closer look reveals that contract farming usually leads to welfare improvements where most producers are smallholders (Simmonset al. 2005; Bolwig and Gibbon 2009; Miyataet al. 2009; Bellemare 2012; Bellemare and Novak 2015). This is intuitive because, if the market is mostly supplied by smallholders who face similar production costs, contracts would only occur if the contracted price is high enough to incentivise most smallholders to participate.However, when large holders are also existent, there could be some room for arbitrage for the downstream contractor,and smallholders would therefore lose. This is likely the case when the contracted price is large enough to attract large holders with their economies of scale and thus lower per unit production costs, but is not sufficient to offset the higher production costs faced by smallholders. Hence, the smallholder welfare impacts of contract farming may vary with the supply-side market structure.

    Fig. 1 depicts two different scenarios: with homogeneous producers (smallholders) and with heterogeneous producers (both small and large holders). In each graph,the upper block shows the cumulative percentage of total market production plotted against the cumulative percentage of the corresponding producers ranked by farm size from small to large, which is comparable to the Lorenz curve income distribution. The lower block,on the other hand, shows the average production cost among producers ranked in exactly the same manner.Therefore, with homogeneous producers, the cumulative production share curve is the 45-degree line and the average production cost is the same for all producers, as shown in Fig. 1-A. While with heterogeneous producers,the cumulative production share curve is below the 45-degree line as large holders produce disproportionally more than smallholders, and the average production cost is downward sloping given economies of scale that lowers the average cost when production increases. In both cases,for a certain among of production is to be delivered to the downstream contractor. With homogeneous producers,the contracted price is equal to the average production cost (a higher contracted price is not as profitable for the contractor while a lower contracted price generates a loss for farmers and thus may not be accepted). Producers ranked from b to c participate in contract farming in this case. With heterogeneous producers, however, only a small number of large producers participate in contract farming (from b to c), whose average production costs are below the contracted price, yet participation is not profitable for smaller producers ranked from a to b as their costs are higher than the contracted price. These smaller producers may therefore opt out of contract farming and look for alternative marketing opportunities to obtain higher profits.

    Although the above literature has intensively explored the welfare implications of contract farming in a variety of countries with almost homogeneous smallholders, less is known about possible impacts with the coexistence of small and large holders, and how expected profitability could affect the participation of smallholders in contract farming. This information, however, is needed to assist policy designs aimed at improving smallholder welfare and ensuring reasonable allocation of benefits associated with contract farming. With the simultaneous presence of heterogeneous farmers, the broiler industry in China is an ideal opportunity to analyse the smallholder welfare in this regard.

    Fig. 1 Contract farming with different supply-side market structures. A, contract farming with homogeneous producers (smallholders).B, contract farming with heterogeneous producers (small and large holders).

    3. Data and method

    The current study is facilitated by a recent national household survey of Chinese broiler producers implemented from June to August, 2015. Six provinces (autonomous region) are covered: Jilin, Hebei, Shandong, Hubei,Guangdong and Guangxi, which cover a wide spectrum of aggregate broiler production levels in the country and jointly represent 43% broiler meat production in China.The first three provinces are in northern China, while the latter three provinces (autonomous region) are in southern China. Stratified sampling strategy has been used for data collection. Within each stratum (province), four to five broiler-producing towns were randomly selected from a list of all broiler-producing towns provided by local agricultural experimental stations, and broiler producers were then randomly selected from producing household lists provided by the village committees. The survey was implemented through face-to-face interviews with farm household heads by the research team that consists of one professor and four doctoral students in the research field of poultry farm management. In our survey, 27 towns were selected with 15 farmers from each town, generating a sample frame of 405 broiler producers. Of these farmers, five refused to participate in the interviews, reducing the total sample to 400. However, in many cases the interviews were also interrupted mid-way through, or cancelled if the farmer was called away and an alternative time could not be identified. In the end, 373 questionnaires were conducted.367 questionnaires were finally deemed as complete with all information appropriately recorded, suggesting a valid response rate of 98.39%. These 367 producers thus serve as the full sample of our analysis.

    Three types of contracts are existent in our data: 1) firm contract, 2) cooperative contract, and 3) hybrid contract.Firm contract (firm+producer) is the most popular contract type, which occurs directly between the downstream processor (firm) and broiler producer. Cooperative contracts(cooperative+producer) are less common yet still existent in many areas, with the downstream contractor being the agricultural marketing cooperative rather than the firm.Unlike the firm, an agricultural marketing cooperative is an entity jointly owned and operated by producers, which pools their individual resources to facilitate final marketing.Hybrid contracts (firm+cooperative+producer) have also been observed in the last decade among Chinese broiler producers due to the beliefs that individual farmers can barely negotiate with large downstream contractors but agricultural cooperatives can generally represent farmers’economic interests. In a hybrid contract, the agricultural cooperative negotiates and contracts with the downstreamfirm on behalf of individual farmers who collectively operate the cooperative, while the agreement between the cooperative and individual farmers are pre-arranged.Therefore, the hybrid contract consists of two contracts,one between the cooperative and the firm, and the other between individual farmers and the cooperative. We further differentiate cooperative contract from hybrid contract by the market role of the cooperative. In the cooperative contract,the cooperative takes full responsibility of final-stage broiler marketing and directly deals with consumers (e.g., individual consumers, restaurants, school cafeterias); while in the hybrid contract, the cooperative does not participate in finalstage broiler marketing but contracts with a downstream business for further broiler processing.

    These contract types differ in strengths and weaknesses.While firm contract is perhaps the most straightforward type,it is often criticized as exploitive due to the weak bargaining power of individual producers (Grosh 1994; Little 1994).Cooperative contract, while voicing the needs of producers,can be inadvertently constrained by their lack of knowledge,skills, market information or appropriate business strategies.As a comparison, hybrid contract can help build a more stable relationship among producers and downstream agents as it both strengthens the collective bargaining power of producers and eases market information transmission back to producers given clear downstream needs, yet in reality it is more difficult to establish given the multiple parties involved and the difficulties of negotiation.

    In our survey, all the contracts were written and were signed before broiler production. Focus group study suggests farmers generally believe written contracts are better than oral ones in terms of securing the contracted marketing channel and clarifying terms and conditions(thereby facilitating easier conflict resolution in case of need). To create a contract, the downstream contractor first offers the written contract that specifies the quality, price, and production details including the time of transaction. Focus group study suggests product quality is a major incentive to use contracts, which accords with earlier literature (e.g.,Guoet al. 2007). Then negotiation occurs and the contract is signed when terms and conditions are agreed upon, and so the contracted price can vary among producers. In each contract type, the downstream contractor partly shares some of the responsibilities of broiler breed provision, technology training, consulting, and disease control practices, which results in looser contract structures as compared to vertical integration commonly observed in horticultural production.However, the contract relationship is reasonably stable as most farmers contract with the same downstream entity over the years given that the number of downstream contractors are limited in most localities. The nonparticipants of broiler production contracts always sold their broilers directly to the market in our data.

    Table 1 presents the summary statistics of the full samples and subsamples broken down by participation status of broiler contract farming and contract types.Household head characteristics, farm characteristics and broiler production practices are respectively presented in three panels. Among surveyed broiler producers, 59.4%(218 producers) participated in firm contract, whereas much fewer participated in either cooperative (46 producers)or hybrid (25 producers) contracts. The remaining 78 producers (21.3%) directly sold their broilers to the market without any contract engagement. While most household head and farm characteristics were very similar across these subsamples, firm contract participants did appear to be more likely female-headed and less likely Communist Party members, while hybrid contract participants were the most educated group with the lowest proportion of risk-averse producers. Nonparticipants of broiler contract farming looked rather alike, except that they possessed an above-average education level and there were fewer village cadres among them. Regarding farm characteristics, hybrid contract participants had the largest land area, which was about twice that of firm and cooperative contract participants and one third larger than that of nonparticipants. Moreover,nonparticipants were more likely to raise local broiler breeds and to be close to major markets. Most of these discrepancies, however, are small.

    More interesting patterns can be seen from a simple cost-benefit analysis of broiler production among surveyed farmers. Nonparticipants had the smallest annual production,which is about half that of the contract participants, which accords with earlier observations that contract farming might favour larger producers (Little and Watts 1994; Singh 2002; Dev and Rao 2005). On the other hand, the annual production of hybrid contract participants was the largest.Moreover, although hybrid contract participants realised the smallest profit per broiler, their total broiler income was still the highest among all subgroups given their largest annual production.

    A comparison among all subgroups further suggests that economies of scale are evident, as annual production and per broiler production cost rank in exactly reversed order.The average broiler weight at farm gate is the smallest for nonparticipants and their per broiler production cost is the highest, which could be partly due to the fact that there was no technological support from downstream contractors.However, the broiler prices they received directly from the market were substantially higher than those offered by contractors, and therefore the profit per broiler for nonparticipants (6.090 CNY or 0.968 USD in 2015) was averaged 327% that of all contract participants. As a result,even with the smallest annual production, the total broiler income of nonparticipants was not necessarily lower than(e.g., firm) contract participants. This is consistent with earlier findings (Verhaegen and Van Huylenbroeck 2001),and these observations imply that it might not be profitable for the former to participate in contract farming. To test this,we implement a simple counterfactual exercise by replacing the individual broiler market prices nonparticipants received with the province-level average contract price participants received. In that case, 74 out of 78 nonparticipants would have negative profits if they were participants, which confirms the above speculation.

    The above observation accords with our hypothesis that contract farming could have opposite welfare results between smaller and larger producers. To investigate the role of farm size in broiler contract farming participation,there is a need to further implement quantitative analysis where multiple factors are simultaneously controlled for. It is towards such analysis that we now turn.

    Table 1 Descriptive statistics of full samples and subsamples by contract type

    4. Results

    We employ multinomial logistic regression modelling to investigate the possible effect of farm size in broiler contract farming participation. Multinomial logistic regression is specifically useful in predicting the probabilities of mutually exclusive discrete choices with a set of independent variables (Greene 2012). In our case, the four discrete choices are firm contract participation, cooperative contract participation, hybrid contract participation and nonparticipation. Multinomial logistic regression is appropriate in our analysis because on one hand, a simple logistic regression with the binary outcome of participation/nonparticipation would not be capable to differentiate possible heterogeneity among choices over three contract types. On the other hand, contract participation decision and contract choice could not be separated as both were made before broiler production (or a nested logistic model would be more appropriate). Independent variables in our analysis include household head characteristics, farm characteristics and annual broiler production as described in Table 1. Broiler sales price, production cost and profit measures are not included as predictors because they were realised during or after the production process, and could not logically affect the participation decision or contract choice made before production. Neither included is broiler breed,which is usually provided by the downstream contractors if the producer participates in contract farming and is not a separate decision. However, annual production is included as it is the best available indicator of economies of scale, which might not change much during a single year.Finally, town dummies are included to capture any possible unobserved heterogeneity across localities.

    Empirical estimation of the multinomial logistic regression relies on the assumption of independence of irrelevant alternatives. It states that the odds, or relative probability, of preferring one choice over another are independent from the presence or absence of other alternatives, which therefore can be considered as “irrelevant”. We proceed with formal Hausman-type tests to see whether this assumption holds since the violation of which could invalidate our results, andfind that it does.

    現(xiàn)行國家評價體系中一級指標還有“保護措施”一項,用以評價保護措施的合理性、完善性和執(zhí)行力度。由于本文詞頻分析中出現(xiàn)的與保護管理相關的“管理、治理”二詞占比較低,故沒有將“保護措施”作為一級指標,而是在三級指標中出現(xiàn)。

    A potential concern of direct maximum likelihood estimation of the multinomial logistic model regards the possible endogeneity of annual broiler production, a decision made by the producer, which could result in biased and inconsistent estimates. Endogeneity has been recognized in contract choices in agricultural production (Ackerberg and Botticini 2002), yet addressing endogeneity in a multinomial logistic regression is technically very difficult (Wooldridge 2015). In our case, we employ the two-step control function estimation procedure proposed by Wooldridge (2015).In the first step, we estimate simple linear regression using an excluded instrument and covariates against the endogenous variable of annual broiler production, and obtain the residuals. In the second step, we then estimate a multinomial logistic model using the residual as the control function along with covariates. Standard errors are finally obtained using bootstrapping.

    The excluded instrument in our analysis is the area of broiler production facilities, which should intuitively affect annual broiler production but not affect broiler contract choice other than through annual production, thereby meeting the criteria of the instrumental variable. The pairwise correlation coefficient between the instrument and annual broiler production is 0.57, probably not as high as one may speculate, because 1) the different practices among producers lead to varying broiler densities during production,and 2) certain off-farm employment opportunities have prevented the broiler production facilities to reach their full capacities. In the first-step regression, the overallF-value is 41.76 (with aP-value of 0.000), suggesting the excluded instrument is reasonably strong.

    In the multinomial logistic regression, nonparticipation is set as the default outcome. Moreover, we should focus on the average partial effects of covariates to ease the interpretation of results. Table 2 presents the average partial effects obtained by estimating the average structural function (Wooldridge 2015). The overall model specification is statistically significant at the 1% level, suggesting all covariates together successfully explain part of the outcome variations.

    Among all covariates, annual production, which captures economies of scale, is statistically significant in all contract choices. This is in line with recent literature (Abebeet al.2016). Specifically, the probabilities of participating in firm,cooperative and hybrid contracts would be 0.010, 0.013 and 0.005 higher as annual production level increases by 1 000 broilers. While the average partial effects are small, the actual differences may not necessarily be. The interquartile range in annual production in our data is 30 000 broilers,which implies that the probabilities of participating in each type of contract can be 30, 39 and 15% higher for the median large producer (75% percentile of annual production–45 000 broilers) than for the median small producer (25%percentile of annual production –15 000 broilers). Thesefindings confirm our earlier observation that smallholders would be less likely to participate in broiler contract farming.

    Several patterns of the associations between other covariates and contract choices are also worth discussion.Being a village cadre encourages firm contract participation,while being a Communist Party member discourages it. In China, village cadres are usually experienced,entrepreneurial and more capable farmers who take the lead in economic activities, while Party members tend to be conservative individuals who are more likely to follow instructions of the local government. As very few producers were both village cadres and Party members in our data,these contradictory effects could simply reflect the conflicting roles of these engagements in this foremost contract type.While education does not seem to stimulate contract farming in general, better educated producers are less likely to participate in cooperative contract, where the cooperative is run by farmers and represent their economic interests.Moreover, risk-averse producers are found more likely to participate in either firm or cooperative contract, which is also intuitive given the more secure marketing channel with contract farming, though such association is not seen with hybrid contract participation. Most other covariates do not seem to be correlated with contract choices.

    Table 2 Multinomial logistic control function estimation of broiler contract choices (n=367)1)

    5. Discussion

    These findings further imply that it could be a rational choice for small producers to opt out of contract farming,which differs from the existing concern that they might be passively excluded from participation given that downstream contractors would prefer large producers (Little and Watts 1994; Singh 2002; Dev and Rao 2005). The underlying belief of the latter argument is that contract farming could potentially benefit all producers, and therefore nonparticipation would result in undesirable welfare loss for small producers,which is not the case in our study. Specifically, the poultry industry in China has been through rapid structural change where farmers increasingly specialise in broiler production,leading to the coexistence of small and large producers(Xie and Marchant 2015), which would largely explain the unprofitability of smaller producers in contract farming. This coexistence could be temporary and might fade over time given the progressive specialisation in broiler production and the fast increase of productivity among remaining broiler producers (Xinet al. 2016). However, our results are still of policy importance because, although broiler industry in China has been transitioning from smallholder-dominated production to large-scale contract farming, the ongoing process may take a long time and many small broiler producers are still expected to exist in the foreseeable future. Moreover, our data may also mirror the future market patterns of smallholder agriculture which is widely existent in agrarian economies and yet to be modernised. Hence,rather than contradicting recent literature that documents positive smallholder welfare impacts in those economies(e.g., Simmonset al. 2005; Bolwig and Gibbon 2009; Miyataet al. 2009; Bellemare 2012; Bellemare and Novak 2015),the current study complements it in terms of forecasting possible smallholder welfare scenarios that might occur as markets evolve.

    As contract farming may benefit smallholders only if they provide most of market supply, a key question is about the future of smallholders given the increasing prevalence of contract farming with agricultural modernisation.Expectedly, not all small producers would continue broiler production, increase productivity or participate in contract farming. While the welfare consequences of quitting broiler production are not necessarily undesirable, especially when outside opportunities are more profitable, possible impacts on remaining small producers still demand more attention.Specifically, as producers are price-driven, it is necessary to investigate how evolving market prices affect smallholder welfare.

    One interesting observation in our data is that the market prices received by nonparticipants of contract farming were much higher than the contracted prices for participants(Table 1). While middlemen’s profits might partly explain this difference, more can be revealed through a simple comparison of broiler breeds of nonparticipants. Among 76 nonparticipants, 33 produced broilers of improved breeds and 45 produced broilers of local breeds. The average price received by the former group (11.67 CNY, or 1.86 USD in 2015) is significantly lower than that of the latter group (19.28 CNY, or 3.07 USD in 2015,P-value through pairwiset-test: 0.003). This pattern, along with the fact that nonparticipants produce broilers of local breeds the most (Table 1), confirms earlier observation that Chinese consumers generally prefer “l(fā)ocal” chicken, which are free-range, slowly-growing with poor feed conversion, but with better meat quality in terms of flavour, tenderness,fat deposition, muscle fibre composition, as well as visual appearances (Yang and Jiang 2005). Therefore, consumers’willingness to pay for those “l(fā)ocal” chicken could be much higher. The implication of this consumer preference can be more profound when placed in the context regarding the future of small producers. A possible strategy is to meet these market needs by specialising in “l(fā)ocal” chicken or poultry products for which small producers possess a comparative advantage. This has already taken place in multiple food sectors. For example, organic food production has experienced an annual farmland increase of 8.9%between 2001 and 2011 to meet the increasing demand(Paull 2011). In the broiler industry, possible opportunities similarly exist for not only organic but also free-range chicken given their price privileges (Husaket al. 2008). Even in developed countries, the market opportunity for both organic and free range poultry products is yet to be fully developed(Castelliniet al. 2008). Specialising in these products could therefore be a possible long-term business strategy for small broiler producers given that contract farming is not profitable.

    6. Conclusion

    We investigate whether contract farming is a financially good option for small broiler producers using a recent nationally representative survey in China. In contrast with many recent studies, we find that contract farming does not benefit small producers in face of larger competitors, the latter of which assume lower production costs given their economies of scale. Descriptive and quantitative analyses further show that small producers were not disadvantageous in terms of socioeconomic characteristics. Certainly, low profits made them opt out of contract farming, given the much higher prices they received from directly selling to the market.Therefore, the current study complements recent empirical literature in extending the almost homogeneous supplyside market structure to cover the coexistence of small and large producers, and conclude that contract farming may not be able to effectively improve smallholder welfare in the latter case.

    We further discuss that small broiler producers may consider alternative opportunities to continue operating in the poultry industry, such as specialising in organic and free-range chicken, which better utilises their comparative advantages. Full cost-benefit analysis of these strategies,however, is beyond the scope of this study. Data limitations further exclude us from investigating the smallholder welfare dynamics of contract farming over time, especially with market structure evolvement from homogeneous small producers to the coexistence of small and large producers.As a first study on broiler contract farming in China, ourfindings only speak to this specific industry and more research is needed to establish external validity. These remaining issues are open for further investigation that could build on the current analysis to better derive policy implications regarding the welfare impacts of contract farming.

    Acknowledgements

    This study is supported by the earmarked fund for the Agricultural Science and Technology Innovation Program,Chinese Academy of Agricultural Sciences (ASTIPIAED-2017) and the Modern Agro-industry Technology Research System, the Ministry of Agriculture of China(CARS-42-G24). We thank Prof. Liu Chunfang, Dr. E Yuzhou and Miss Zhou Rui from Chinese Academy of Agricultural Sciences for their assistance in survey data collection and the supports of staffs from broilers test stations in Hebei,Jilin, Shandong, Guangxi, Hubei and Guangdong.

    Abebe G K, Bijman J, Royer A. 2016. Are middlemen facilitators or barriers to improve smallholders’ welfare in rural economies? Empirical evidence from Ethiopia.Journal of Rural Studies, 43, 203–213.

    Ackerberg D A, Botticini M. 2002. Endogenous matching and the empirical determinants of contract form.Journal of Political Economy, 110, 564–591.

    Barrett C B, Bachke M E, Bellemare M F, Michelson H C,Narayanan S, Walker T F. 2012. Smallholder participation in contract farming: Comparative evidence from five countries.World Development, 40, 715–730.

    Bellemare M F. 2012. As you sow, so shall you reap: The welfare impacts of contract farming.World Development,40, 1418–1434.

    Bellemare M F, Novak L. 2015. Contract farming and food security.American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 99,357–378.

    Bolwig S, Gibbon P. 2009. The economics of smallholder organic contract farming in tropical Africa.World Development, 37,1094–1104.

    Castellini C, Berri C, Le Bihan-Duval E, Martino G. 2008.Qualitative attributes and consumer perception of organic and free-range poultry meat.World’s Poultry Science Journal, 64, 500–512.

    Dev S M, Rao N C. 2005. Food processing and contract farming in Andhra Pradesh: A small farmer perspective.Economic and Political Weekly, 40, 2705–2713.

    Fukase E, Martin W. 2016. Who will feed China in the 21st century? Income growth and food demand and supply in China.Journal of Agricultural Economics, 67, 3–23.

    Glover D. 1990. Contract farming and outgrower schemes in east and southern Africa.Journal of Agricultural Economics,41,303–315.

    Glover D J. 1984. Contract farming and smallholder outgrower schemes in less developed countries.World Development,12, 1143–1157.

    Greene W H. 2012.Econometric Analysis. 7th ed. Prentice Hall,Upper Saddle River. pp. 763–766.

    Grosh B. 1994. Contract farming in Africa: An application of the new institutional economies.Journal of African Economics,3, 231–261.

    Guo H, Jolly R W, Zhu J. 2007. Contract farming in China:Perspectives of farm households and agribusiness firms.Comparative Economic Studies, 49, 285–312.

    Harwood J, Heifner R, Coble K, Perry J, Somwaru A. 1999.Managing Risk in Farming: Concepts, Research, and Analysis.Market and Trade Economics Division and Resource Economics Division, Economic Research Service,U.S. Department of Agriculture. Agricultural Economic Report No. 774.

    Husak R L, Sebranek J G, Bregendahl K. 2008. A survey of commercially available broilers marketed as organic, freerange, and conventional broilers for cooked meat yields,meat composition, and relative value.Poultry Science,87, 2367–2376.

    Ke B, Han Y. 2007. Poultry sector in China: Structural changes during the past decade and future trends. In: Thieme O,Pilling D, eds.,Poultry in the 21st Century: Avian Influenza and Beyond. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Bangkok, Rome, Italy. pp. 1–33.

    Little P. 1994. Contract farming and the development question.In: Little P, Watts M, eds.,Living Under Contract: Contract Farming and Agrarian Transformation in Sub-Saharan Africa. University of Wisconsin Press, Madison.

    Little P D, Watts M J. 1994.Living Under Contract: Contract Farming and Agrarian Transformation in the Sub-Saharan Africa. University of Wisconsin Press, Madison.

    Martinez-Gomez F, Aboites-Manrique G, Constance D H.2013. Neoliberal restructuring, neoregulation, and the Mexican poultry industry.Agriculture and Human Values,30, 495–510.

    Merry F D, Sheikh P A, Mcgrath D G. 2004. The role of informal contracts in the growth of small cattle herds on thefloodplains of the Lower Amazon.Agriculture and Human Values, 21, 377–386.

    Miyata S, Minot N, Hu D. 2009. Impact of contract farming on income: Linking small farmers, packers, and supermarkets in China.World Development, 37, 1781–1790.

    Narayanan S. 2014. Profits from participation in high value agriculture: Evidence of heterogeneous benefits in contract farming schemes in Southern India.Food Policy, 44,142–157.

    Nguyen A T, Dzator J, Nadolny A. 2015. Does contract farming improve productivity and income of farmers? A review of theory and evidence.Journal of Developing Areas, 49,531–538.

    Oya C. 2012. Contract farming in Sub-Saharan Africa: A survey of approaches, debates and issues.Journal of Agrarian Change, 12, 1–33.

    Paull J. 2011. The Uptake of organic agriculture: A decade of worldwide development.Journal of Social and Development Sciences, 2, 111–120.

    Raynolds L T. 2002. Wages for wives: Renegotiating gender and production relations in contract farming in the Dominican Republic.World Development, 30, 783–798.

    Reardon T, Barrett C B. 2000. Agroindustrialization, globalization,and international development: An overview of issues,patterns, and determinants.Agricultural Economics, 23,195–205.

    Simmons P, Winters P, Patricka I. 2005. An analysis of contract farming in East Java, Bali, and Lombok, Indonesia.Agricultural Economics, 33, 513–525.

    Singh S. 2002. Contracting out solutions: Political economy of contract farming in the Indian Punjab.World Development,30, 1621–1638.

    Sivramkrishna S, Jyotishi A. 2008. Monopsonistic exploitation in contract farming: Articulating a strategy for grower cooperation.Journal of International Development, 20,280–296.

    Verhaegen I, Van Huylenbroeck G. 2001. Costs and benefits for farmers participating in innovative marketing channels for quality food products.Journal of Rural Studies, 17, 443–456.

    Welsh R. 2009. Farm and market structure, industrial regulation and rural community welfare: Conceptual and methodological issues.Agriculture and Human Values,26, 21–28.

    Wooldridge J M. 2015. Control function methods in applied econometrics.Journal of Human Resources, 50, 420–445.

    Xie C, Marchant M A. 2015. Supplying China’s growing appetite for poultry.International Food and Agribusiness Management Review, 18, 115–136.

    Xin X, Zhang Y, Wang J, Nuetah J A. 2016. Effects of farm size on technical efficiency in China’s broiler sector: A stochastic meta-frontier approach.Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 64, 493–516.

    Yang N, Jiang R S. 2005. Recent advances in breeding for quality chickens.World’s Poultry Science Journal, 61,373–381.

    猜你喜歡
    詞頻保護措施現(xiàn)行
    城市道路施工中地下管線保護措施
    沅江懷化段漁業(yè)資源增殖保護措施
    基于詞頻分析法的社區(qū)公園歸屬感營建要素研究
    園林科技(2021年3期)2022-01-19 03:17:48
    抓現(xiàn)行
    地面氣象觀測場防雷保護措施分析
    淺談我國現(xiàn)行的房產(chǎn)稅
    活力(2019年15期)2019-09-25 07:21:38
    被抓了現(xiàn)行
    現(xiàn)行企業(yè)內(nèi)部控制制度探討
    高山茶園如何做好防凍保護措施
    詞頻,一部隱秘的歷史
    一个人免费在线观看的高清视频| 欧美亚洲 丝袜 人妻 在线| 大型黄色视频在线免费观看| 亚洲 欧美一区二区三区| 国产国语露脸激情在线看| 男女床上黄色一级片免费看| 在线亚洲精品国产二区图片欧美| 亚洲精品乱久久久久久| 免费观看av网站的网址| av线在线观看网站| 制服人妻中文乱码| 亚洲欧美一区二区三区黑人| 国产精品香港三级国产av潘金莲| 色老头精品视频在线观看| 欧美黄色淫秽网站| 国产成人影院久久av| 岛国毛片在线播放| 欧美av亚洲av综合av国产av| 亚洲五月色婷婷综合| 免费在线观看日本一区| 国产极品粉嫩免费观看在线| 午夜福利免费观看在线| 亚洲美女黄片视频| 成人永久免费在线观看视频 | 99久久人妻综合| 一区二区三区国产精品乱码| 一区二区三区激情视频| avwww免费| 99久久国产精品久久久| 国产一区二区三区综合在线观看| 色播在线永久视频| 亚洲天堂av无毛| 男女之事视频高清在线观看| 国产高清激情床上av| 黄网站色视频无遮挡免费观看| 一级毛片精品| 在线看a的网站| 色94色欧美一区二区| 美女午夜性视频免费| 悠悠久久av| 一本大道久久a久久精品| 黄色怎么调成土黄色| 国产亚洲精品久久久久5区| 99re在线观看精品视频| 国产男靠女视频免费网站| 女性被躁到高潮视频| 久久精品国产99精品国产亚洲性色 | 黑人巨大精品欧美一区二区mp4| 黄色片一级片一级黄色片| 久久人妻福利社区极品人妻图片| 亚洲欧美色中文字幕在线| 亚洲精品中文字幕在线视频| 777久久人妻少妇嫩草av网站| 王馨瑶露胸无遮挡在线观看| 欧美成人免费av一区二区三区 | 两人在一起打扑克的视频| 精品国产乱码久久久久久男人| 欧美老熟妇乱子伦牲交| 在线观看www视频免费| 黑人操中国人逼视频| av一本久久久久| 国产成人av教育| 久久亚洲真实| 在线永久观看黄色视频| 亚洲三区欧美一区| 宅男免费午夜| 亚洲国产欧美网| 久久99一区二区三区| 国产在线视频一区二区| 国产日韩欧美视频二区| 黄色a级毛片大全视频| 我要看黄色一级片免费的| 国产精品久久久人人做人人爽| 成在线人永久免费视频| 一边摸一边抽搐一进一出视频| 精品国产一区二区三区久久久樱花| 国产精品一区二区在线不卡| 1024香蕉在线观看| 国产激情久久老熟女| bbb黄色大片| 一本—道久久a久久精品蜜桃钙片| 男男h啪啪无遮挡| 免费不卡黄色视频| 变态另类成人亚洲欧美熟女 | 99国产精品一区二区三区| 亚洲黑人精品在线| 亚洲 国产 在线| 91麻豆av在线| 国产精品自产拍在线观看55亚洲 | 午夜福利视频精品| 久热爱精品视频在线9| 亚洲国产欧美日韩在线播放| 精品亚洲成a人片在线观看| h视频一区二区三区| 欧美精品啪啪一区二区三区| 亚洲精品一卡2卡三卡4卡5卡| 嫩草影视91久久| 午夜福利一区二区在线看| av有码第一页| 高清黄色对白视频在线免费看| 黄色片一级片一级黄色片| 欧美成人免费av一区二区三区 | 国产亚洲午夜精品一区二区久久| 一二三四社区在线视频社区8| 怎么达到女性高潮| 一区二区三区乱码不卡18| 国产精品久久久久久人妻精品电影 | 亚洲中文日韩欧美视频| 老鸭窝网址在线观看| 欧美老熟妇乱子伦牲交| 免费在线观看影片大全网站| 国产男女内射视频| 夜夜爽天天搞| videos熟女内射| 一级毛片女人18水好多| 久久免费观看电影| 色在线成人网| 99精品在免费线老司机午夜| 国内毛片毛片毛片毛片毛片| 不卡一级毛片| 大片电影免费在线观看免费| 亚洲精品美女久久久久99蜜臀| 我要看黄色一级片免费的| 黄片大片在线免费观看| 大型黄色视频在线免费观看| 国产亚洲午夜精品一区二区久久| 岛国毛片在线播放| 亚洲五月色婷婷综合| 在线av久久热| 成人亚洲精品一区在线观看| 欧美日韩av久久| 亚洲黑人精品在线| 国产精品九九99| 熟女少妇亚洲综合色aaa.| 在线观看人妻少妇| 91麻豆av在线| 久久久水蜜桃国产精品网| 青青草视频在线视频观看| 最黄视频免费看| 免费女性裸体啪啪无遮挡网站| 99在线人妻在线中文字幕 | 91老司机精品| av片东京热男人的天堂| 在线观看免费日韩欧美大片| 亚洲av国产av综合av卡| 高清黄色对白视频在线免费看| 国产精品九九99| 国产日韩欧美在线精品| 啪啪无遮挡十八禁网站| 亚洲视频免费观看视频| 国产亚洲一区二区精品| 曰老女人黄片| 一级毛片精品| 美女扒开内裤让男人捅视频| 别揉我奶头~嗯~啊~动态视频| 欧美精品人与动牲交sv欧美| 极品教师在线免费播放| 亚洲av电影在线进入| 日韩三级视频一区二区三区| 日韩熟女老妇一区二区性免费视频| 99在线人妻在线中文字幕 | 国产午夜精品久久久久久| 中文欧美无线码| 久久久精品94久久精品| 欧美激情久久久久久爽电影 | 手机成人av网站| 欧美日韩亚洲高清精品| 国产成人精品在线电影| 老司机午夜十八禁免费视频| 我要看黄色一级片免费的| 国产精品久久久av美女十八| 国产av精品麻豆| 亚洲精品国产一区二区精华液| 下体分泌物呈黄色| 中文字幕制服av| 亚洲第一青青草原| 亚洲人成电影观看| 国产亚洲午夜精品一区二区久久| 欧美日韩黄片免| 99re6热这里在线精品视频| 欧美日韩视频精品一区| 青青草视频在线视频观看| 久久精品亚洲熟妇少妇任你| 精品国产一区二区三区四区第35| cao死你这个sao货| 法律面前人人平等表现在哪些方面| 日日夜夜操网爽| 国产在线一区二区三区精| 午夜福利在线免费观看网站| 热99re8久久精品国产| 国产精品一区二区在线不卡| 好男人电影高清在线观看| 日韩视频一区二区在线观看| 精品熟女少妇八av免费久了| 91大片在线观看| 一本综合久久免费| 久久久精品区二区三区| 建设人人有责人人尽责人人享有的| 国产在线观看jvid| 黄片大片在线免费观看| 50天的宝宝边吃奶边哭怎么回事| 大型黄色视频在线免费观看| 精品国产一区二区三区久久久樱花| 久久久久视频综合| 欧美精品啪啪一区二区三区| 人妻 亚洲 视频| 国产黄色免费在线视频| 国产av国产精品国产| 天天躁夜夜躁狠狠躁躁| 免费高清在线观看日韩| 国产成人欧美在线观看 | 欧美国产精品一级二级三级| 18禁观看日本| 亚洲av电影在线进入| 69精品国产乱码久久久| 一级毛片电影观看| 国产无遮挡羞羞视频在线观看| 成年人免费黄色播放视频| 国产精品亚洲av一区麻豆| a级毛片黄视频| 久久久精品免费免费高清| 在线观看免费午夜福利视频| 亚洲午夜理论影院| 无遮挡黄片免费观看| 成人手机av| 国产精品电影一区二区三区 | 日韩欧美三级三区| 欧美精品一区二区免费开放| 多毛熟女@视频| 亚洲伊人色综图| 亚洲精品中文字幕一二三四区 | 久久久精品免费免费高清| 人人妻人人澡人人看| 黑人操中国人逼视频| 欧美av亚洲av综合av国产av| 青草久久国产| 窝窝影院91人妻| 丁香六月天网| 香蕉国产在线看| 中文字幕高清在线视频| 亚洲精品自拍成人| 精品欧美一区二区三区在线| 国产精品99久久99久久久不卡| av欧美777| 国产成人精品无人区| 最新美女视频免费是黄的| 老汉色∧v一级毛片| 91成年电影在线观看| 最新在线观看一区二区三区| 成人特级黄色片久久久久久久 | 日韩一卡2卡3卡4卡2021年| 国产精品98久久久久久宅男小说| 亚洲视频免费观看视频| 国产精品美女特级片免费视频播放器 | 国产淫语在线视频| 国产av一区二区精品久久| 亚洲精品国产精品久久久不卡| 精品国产乱码久久久久久男人| 超色免费av| 多毛熟女@视频| 9色porny在线观看| 国产精品98久久久久久宅男小说| 新久久久久国产一级毛片| 中文字幕人妻丝袜一区二区| 交换朋友夫妻互换小说| 菩萨蛮人人尽说江南好唐韦庄| 成人18禁在线播放| av电影中文网址| 天堂俺去俺来也www色官网| 天天影视国产精品| 久久中文看片网| 夜夜爽天天搞| 成年女人毛片免费观看观看9 | av线在线观看网站| 亚洲av电影在线进入| 国产精品欧美亚洲77777| 动漫黄色视频在线观看| 国产福利在线免费观看视频| 黄色怎么调成土黄色| 午夜福利视频在线观看免费| 亚洲人成电影免费在线| 国产精品熟女久久久久浪| 国产精品免费一区二区三区在线 | 麻豆国产av国片精品| 一区二区三区乱码不卡18| 久久精品国产亚洲av香蕉五月 | 国产精品亚洲av一区麻豆| 国产精品98久久久久久宅男小说| 国产精品影院久久| 欧美精品一区二区免费开放| 成人永久免费在线观看视频 | 两人在一起打扑克的视频| 国产精品1区2区在线观看. | 国产男女超爽视频在线观看| 午夜久久久在线观看| 亚洲国产成人一精品久久久| 久久久水蜜桃国产精品网| 亚洲avbb在线观看| 亚洲 国产 在线| 亚洲精华国产精华精| 淫妇啪啪啪对白视频| 极品少妇高潮喷水抽搐| 天堂中文最新版在线下载| 丰满迷人的少妇在线观看| 亚洲 国产 在线| 五月开心婷婷网| 免费久久久久久久精品成人欧美视频| 亚洲成人免费电影在线观看| 欧美午夜高清在线| 男人操女人黄网站| 亚洲五月婷婷丁香| 99精国产麻豆久久婷婷| 桃红色精品国产亚洲av| 久久久久久亚洲精品国产蜜桃av| 成年版毛片免费区| 巨乳人妻的诱惑在线观看| 99re6热这里在线精品视频| 中文字幕人妻熟女乱码| 两个人看的免费小视频| 美女国产高潮福利片在线看| 深夜精品福利| 男女免费视频国产| 亚洲国产av新网站| av国产精品久久久久影院| 久久人人97超碰香蕉20202| 肉色欧美久久久久久久蜜桃| 日韩中文字幕视频在线看片| 无限看片的www在线观看| 一个人免费看片子| 亚洲少妇的诱惑av| 一个人免费在线观看的高清视频| 国产黄频视频在线观看| 国产片内射在线| 午夜福利影视在线免费观看| 国产精品98久久久久久宅男小说| tube8黄色片| 少妇被粗大的猛进出69影院| 亚洲人成77777在线视频| 亚洲伊人久久精品综合| 午夜福利视频精品| www.自偷自拍.com| 啦啦啦 在线观看视频| 男人操女人黄网站| 一级毛片精品| 男人舔女人的私密视频| 欧美精品人与动牲交sv欧美| 老司机福利观看| 久久久精品区二区三区| 久久人妻熟女aⅴ| 国精品久久久久久国模美| 亚洲中文字幕日韩| 久久亚洲真实| 久久影院123| 乱人伦中国视频| a在线观看视频网站| 欧美 亚洲 国产 日韩一| 91av网站免费观看| www.精华液| 美国免费a级毛片| 日韩大片免费观看网站| 国产aⅴ精品一区二区三区波| 超碰成人久久| 久久ye,这里只有精品| av天堂久久9| av不卡在线播放| 国产在线观看jvid| 亚洲熟妇熟女久久| 黄片大片在线免费观看| 人妻久久中文字幕网| 大片免费播放器 马上看| 欧美国产精品va在线观看不卡| 99国产极品粉嫩在线观看| 亚洲av日韩精品久久久久久密| 亚洲天堂av无毛| 中文字幕av电影在线播放| 人人妻,人人澡人人爽秒播| 中亚洲国语对白在线视频| 精品少妇内射三级| 人妻 亚洲 视频| 久久这里只有精品19| 女同久久另类99精品国产91| 国产av精品麻豆| 国产精品一区二区免费欧美| 丝袜喷水一区| 如日韩欧美国产精品一区二区三区| 老司机亚洲免费影院| 亚洲熟妇熟女久久| 一级毛片电影观看| 亚洲美女黄片视频| av福利片在线| 国产日韩欧美视频二区| 一区二区三区精品91| 日本黄色视频三级网站网址 | 丰满少妇做爰视频| 亚洲第一av免费看| av视频免费观看在线观看| 在线观看www视频免费| 精品国产一区二区三区久久久樱花| 日韩有码中文字幕| 91九色精品人成在线观看| 一个人免费看片子| 大型av网站在线播放| 高潮久久久久久久久久久不卡| 亚洲国产看品久久| 午夜福利在线观看吧| 欧美日韩视频精品一区| 在线十欧美十亚洲十日本专区| 精品一区二区三卡| 如日韩欧美国产精品一区二区三区| 日日摸夜夜添夜夜添小说| 丝袜在线中文字幕| 亚洲欧美色中文字幕在线| 丝袜美腿诱惑在线| 99精品在免费线老司机午夜| 亚洲av美国av| av片东京热男人的天堂| 日韩 欧美 亚洲 中文字幕| 久久久久久亚洲精品国产蜜桃av| 激情视频va一区二区三区| 中国美女看黄片| 老熟妇乱子伦视频在线观看| 免费观看av网站的网址| 国产精品国产高清国产av | 亚洲性夜色夜夜综合| 啦啦啦中文免费视频观看日本| 一本一本久久a久久精品综合妖精| 国产高清videossex| 搡老岳熟女国产| 1024视频免费在线观看| 亚洲欧美激情在线| 亚洲精品国产精品久久久不卡| 人妻久久中文字幕网| 悠悠久久av| 久久免费观看电影| 在线观看免费高清a一片| 亚洲熟妇熟女久久| 国产高清国产精品国产三级| 国产91精品成人一区二区三区 | 欧美激情久久久久久爽电影 | 国产精品.久久久| 亚洲熟女毛片儿| 国产免费视频播放在线视频| 女性被躁到高潮视频| 丝瓜视频免费看黄片| 亚洲第一av免费看| 国产伦人伦偷精品视频| 精品国产乱码久久久久久小说| 黑人猛操日本美女一级片| 国产精品熟女久久久久浪| 亚洲精品美女久久久久99蜜臀| 亚洲视频免费观看视频| 亚洲,欧美精品.| 亚洲精品中文字幕一二三四区 | 91老司机精品| 国产日韩欧美视频二区| 亚洲伊人色综图| 国产精品一区二区在线观看99| 亚洲天堂av无毛| 久久人人爽av亚洲精品天堂| 午夜两性在线视频| a级片在线免费高清观看视频| 1024视频免费在线观看| 亚洲欧洲日产国产| 亚洲精品一卡2卡三卡4卡5卡| 日韩一区二区三区影片| 一区二区日韩欧美中文字幕| 欧美精品人与动牲交sv欧美| 日本vs欧美在线观看视频| 伦理电影免费视频| 国产精品1区2区在线观看. | 亚洲久久久国产精品| 一夜夜www| 夜夜夜夜夜久久久久| 一本大道久久a久久精品| 高清视频免费观看一区二区| 午夜老司机福利片| 色播在线永久视频| 精品国产一区二区三区四区第35| 中亚洲国语对白在线视频| av天堂久久9| 一级黄色大片毛片| 考比视频在线观看| 久久精品国产亚洲av高清一级| 一本—道久久a久久精品蜜桃钙片| 国产在视频线精品| 日本欧美视频一区| 亚洲中文av在线| 精品久久久久久电影网| 丁香六月欧美| 在线亚洲精品国产二区图片欧美| 十八禁网站免费在线| 亚洲熟女精品中文字幕| 50天的宝宝边吃奶边哭怎么回事| 免费在线观看影片大全网站| 日韩熟女老妇一区二区性免费视频| 日韩一卡2卡3卡4卡2021年| 亚洲自偷自拍图片 自拍| 无遮挡黄片免费观看| 性色av乱码一区二区三区2| 亚洲免费av在线视频| 精品久久久精品久久久| 天天影视国产精品| 夜夜爽天天搞| 天堂8中文在线网| 日韩免费av在线播放| 国产精品.久久久| 69精品国产乱码久久久| 午夜91福利影院| 国产精品久久久av美女十八| 男女之事视频高清在线观看| 亚洲欧洲日产国产| 黑人巨大精品欧美一区二区mp4| 日韩欧美一区二区三区在线观看 | 两人在一起打扑克的视频| 一本大道久久a久久精品| 亚洲精品久久成人aⅴ小说| 欧美亚洲 丝袜 人妻 在线| 黄色a级毛片大全视频| 十八禁高潮呻吟视频| 男女床上黄色一级片免费看| 久久香蕉激情| 欧美乱码精品一区二区三区| 免费看a级黄色片| 久久精品国产亚洲av高清一级| 精品午夜福利视频在线观看一区 | 首页视频小说图片口味搜索| 亚洲欧美色中文字幕在线| 无人区码免费观看不卡 | 国产一区二区 视频在线| 日本精品一区二区三区蜜桃| 精品国产国语对白av| 男女下面插进去视频免费观看| 热re99久久精品国产66热6| aaaaa片日本免费| av在线播放免费不卡| 50天的宝宝边吃奶边哭怎么回事| 国产亚洲欧美在线一区二区| 下体分泌物呈黄色| 99精品久久久久人妻精品| 国产日韩欧美在线精品| 精品少妇久久久久久888优播| 免费观看av网站的网址| 欧美亚洲日本最大视频资源| 国产单亲对白刺激| 国产91精品成人一区二区三区 | 国产精品久久久久久人妻精品电影 | 国产亚洲精品久久久久5区| 一区二区三区激情视频| 两人在一起打扑克的视频| 国产不卡av网站在线观看| 丰满少妇做爰视频| 久久九九热精品免费| 极品少妇高潮喷水抽搐| 国产在线精品亚洲第一网站| 俄罗斯特黄特色一大片| 国产日韩欧美视频二区| 在线av久久热| 天堂动漫精品| a级毛片黄视频| 一进一出抽搐动态| 久久久欧美国产精品| 大片免费播放器 马上看| 最新的欧美精品一区二区| 国产在线一区二区三区精| 国产aⅴ精品一区二区三区波| 日韩欧美免费精品| 欧美亚洲日本最大视频资源| 可以免费在线观看a视频的电影网站| 99国产精品免费福利视频| 欧美国产精品va在线观看不卡| 亚洲五月婷婷丁香| 大型黄色视频在线免费观看| 波多野结衣av一区二区av| 国产aⅴ精品一区二区三区波| 91av网站免费观看| 欧美 日韩 精品 国产| 欧美中文综合在线视频| 性高湖久久久久久久久免费观看| 变态另类成人亚洲欧美熟女 | 国产欧美日韩一区二区三| 王馨瑶露胸无遮挡在线观看| 这个男人来自地球电影免费观看| 午夜福利视频在线观看免费| 亚洲欧美日韩高清在线视频 | 精品一区二区三区视频在线观看免费 | 1024香蕉在线观看| 亚洲自偷自拍图片 自拍| 男人操女人黄网站| 久久久精品免费免费高清| 天天躁日日躁夜夜躁夜夜| 久久九九热精品免费| av在线播放免费不卡| 男男h啪啪无遮挡| 嫁个100分男人电影在线观看| 日本欧美视频一区| 亚洲成人手机| 桃红色精品国产亚洲av| 99re在线观看精品视频| 精品高清国产在线一区| 久久精品亚洲av国产电影网| 亚洲国产看品久久| 午夜91福利影院| 两性夫妻黄色片| 国产主播在线观看一区二区| 欧美乱码精品一区二区三区| 久久九九热精品免费| 久久亚洲精品不卡| 一本综合久久免费| 欧美日韩福利视频一区二区| 国产91精品成人一区二区三区 | 男人操女人黄网站| 免费看a级黄色片| 欧美另类亚洲清纯唯美| 1024香蕉在线观看| 99精品在免费线老司机午夜|