• <tr id="yyy80"></tr>
  • <sup id="yyy80"></sup>
  • <tfoot id="yyy80"><noscript id="yyy80"></noscript></tfoot>
  • 99热精品在线国产_美女午夜性视频免费_国产精品国产高清国产av_av欧美777_自拍偷自拍亚洲精品老妇_亚洲熟女精品中文字幕_www日本黄色视频网_国产精品野战在线观看 ?

    Modeling Optimal Fare and Service Provisions for a Crowded Rail Transit Line

    2013-09-25 13:13:14QINFeifeiJIAHaicehng

    QIN Fei-fei,JIA Hai-cehng

    (1.Dep.of Economics and Social Science,Molde University College,Molde N-6402,Norway;2.School of Urban Rail Transportation,Soochow University,Suzhou 215006,Jiangsu,China;3 Dep.of Logistics,Suzhou University of Science and Technology,Suzhou 215011,Jiangsu,China)

    1 Introduction

    Over the lastdecade urban scale and car ownership are both on a substantial growth,leading to increasing traffic congestion and environmental pollution.To help alleviate congestion and protect the environment,the enthusiasm forconstructing rail transit lines is booming in China.In the end of 2008,11 cities had rail transit lines in operation.However,the expected modal shift toward rail transit will only occurifitcan offergreatadvantagesoverits competing modes. Thus,designing an efficient operational scheme has far-reaching impacts not only on the transit line itself,but also on the overall urban transport system.

    In the strategic and tactical planning,fare,frequency and number of carriages are three key design variables[1].Irrespective of ownership,most rail transit operators in China set fares roughly to cover a fixed percentage of total costs and determine frequency according to the rule of thumb of“Maximum Section Load”.Obviously,these decision rules fail to make resources reach Pareto Optimality.To determine what“optimal operational configuration”would look like,we jointly optimize fares,frequency and numberofcarriagesunder alternative management objectives by taking some relevant“externalities,”such as in-vehicle crowding,congestion-relief benefitand noise pollution into consideration.

    The rest of the paper is structured as follows:in Section 2,an in-depth literature review on optimal operation design is presented from two distinct strains.In Section 3,having taken both positive externality and negative externality into account,micro-economic models for profit and social welfare maximization are presented to provide explicit decision rules for fares,frequency,and number of carriages.Furthermore,the comparative static analysis(CSA)is employed to compare the relative order of magnitude between social welfare optima and profit optima.In Section 4,we conduct a detailed numerical case study for Suzhou rail transit line 1 to assess its current operating scheme.Finally,the major findings are summarized in Section 5.

    2 Literature review

    As a response to the substantial change of the urban transport environment,a large body of researches has been increasing over several decades.Particularly,after the appearance of the seminal paper written by Vickrey[2],numerous efforts have been made from two distinct strains in urban transportation economies.

    The first strain directly concerns minimizing“totalsystem costs”.Assumingthe demand is inelastic,it involves a trade-off between two types of resources:those provided by operators and those contributed by passengers—namely their time.This approach was first addressed by Mohring[3,4]and has been extended to include more factors by Jansson et al.[5-8]and recently by Jara-Díaz et al.[9-11].Specific contributions foreach paperin thisstream are presented in Table 1.

    Table 1 Literatures of minimizing total system costs for inelastic demand

    Table 2 Literatures of maximizing social welfare for elastic demand

    In the last decades,although this approach has provided a good guide to improve transit operations,a minor drawback can be easily detected,that is,this approach is merely restricted to the supply side so that passengers’responses to different service levels are left out or hidden behind the user cost concept.Having observed this,the second strand of research emphasizing passengers’reactions to various service combinations should be modeled through the generalized cost-based functions.This approach was put forward first by Nash[12]and then was proved to be rational by Larsen[13].Pertinent references for this approach are Viton et al.[14–19].The summary of important studies in this strand is presented in Table 2.

    In view of the above literatures,it seems that although the bus systemoptimization has received great attention,relatively few efforts have been devoted to the rail transit services,which is the central concern here.The present paper contributes to the existing literatures in two ways.First,the train length,reflected by the number of carriages per train,is optimized in addition to the convention control variables,such as fares and frequency.Another feature that differentiates this paper from previous studies is the incorporation of in-vehicle crowding effect into the operation optimization,which is captured by replacing the constant value of riding time with the proposed invehicle crowding cost function.

    3 Theoretical modeling for rail transit operational configurations

    3.1 Building blocks for analytical mathematical models

    We consider one representative passenger traveling along one rail transit line during a particular period,and his/her traveling choice is based on the generalized cost(G).Hereby,the demand(Q)can be written as:

    We assume the demand function is concave with respect to generalized costs,which indicates?Q/?G<0 and ?2Q/?G2≥ 0 .The generalized cost function comprises the fare charged(p),the riding time costs(Cv)and the waiting time costs(Cw):

    where the in-vehicle time(Tv)and waiting time(Tw)can be converted to monetary values using the value of riding time(Pv)and the value of waiting time (Pw),respectively.Many empiricaland theoretical researches revealed that standing passengers virtually place higher values of riding time than seated passengers do[20].Known as the earliest work,Kraus[21]advocated that the disutility arising from in-vehicle crowding can be considered through a variable value of riding time,which increases with occupancy rate or load factor.Following this,the value of riding time can be decomposed into two parts by introducing the crowding penalty function,ρ,for standing:

    wherePv0is the value of riding time for seating.As a mark-up,the crowding penalty(ρ)varies with the load factor(φ),which is the fraction of the average number of passengers(θ)per departure to the total seating capacity of the train.Iflis the average trip length andLdenotes the route length,the average number of passengers on-board,θ,can be written as:

    Since we adopt number of carriages per train(N)as one of the control variables,the total seating capacity per departure is the product of number of carriages(N)and the number of seats per carriage(σ).Ultimately,the load factor can be expressed as:

    In terms of high-frequency rail transit service,the well-known“wait equals half of the headway”rule can be regarded as a good approximation to represent the average waiting time.Combining all formulas proposed above,the detailed form of the generalized cost is:

    Generally,the total operating costs comprise two parts:fixed costs and variable costs.In the short term,fixed operational costs are such costs that do not vary with outputs.Since the fixed cost component is not relevant to the optimal operation decisions,we can disregard them and only consider variable operating costs.To this end,the variable operating cost can be modeled as:

    whereCois the variable operating costs per hour;c2is the cost proportionate to ridership;c1denotes the incremental cost per departure.Generally,we can assumec1[N]is linear with the number of carriages as

    whereK1stands for the fixed parts that does not vary with the train length andK2is the extra costs of adding one more carriage.It is clear that the operating cost function is slightly convex,i.e.,almost linear.

    From a social macroscopic point of view,the consumer surplusshould beincluded asakey component of social welfare.Commonly,the aggregate consumer surplus can be expressed as the integral function of generalized costs(G):

    whereSdenotes the consumer surplus,which follows that?S/?G=-Q.

    In the case of rail transit,the external effects can be divided into two parts:negative and positive externalities.The main negative externality is noise pollution,which can be treated as varying linearly with frequency.Since one of the important reasons for operating rail transit along arterial roads is to relieve congestion,another external effect is the benefit from congestion relief.Forthe ease ofmodeling,the external benefit of improving traffic congestion is specified as a function of patronage that transfers from private cars.

    whereEBdenotes the external benefit function and parameter γ is the percent of passengers that transfer from private cars.ECis the marginal external cost of running one additional train.Consequently,this type of external cost is linearly proportional to the service frequency(EC·f).

    3.2 Optima under two advocated management objectives

    3.2.1 Social welfare maximization optimal results

    The socialwelfare maximization solution is always viewed as an ideal benchmark to evaluate the efficiency of operation schemes.In this sub-section,wefirstassume thatin the pursuitofPareto efficiency,the public authority aims to maximize social welfare(SW),which can be expressed as the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus,but necessarily should be supplemented by the external costs from noise pollution and the external benefits from relieving surface congestion.

    It is easy to prove that the Hessian matrix of the second derivative of Eq.(11)with respect to control variables is negative semi-definite.Thus,we can rely on equating the first derivatives to zero to express the decision rules for three control variables.

    Firstly,taking the partial derivatives of Eq.(11)with respect to fares gives:

    By setting Eq.(12)equal to zero and factoring out the non-zero item ?Q/?p,the optimal fare per trip(pw)can be written as:

    In what follows,for distinguishing maximizing outputs under different management objectives,the superscriptWindexes the social welfare optimum,and the super index π denotes the profit maximization results.

    Without a budget constraint,the welfare optimal price comprises three parts:the first part is the marginal production cost(c2).The second part is the marginal in-vehiclecrowdingcostsQ(?CV/?Q),which can be viewed as a“mark-up”component to internalize the in-vehicle crowding costs that passengers impose on each other.The third part is the additional external benefits arising from inducing passengers from the under-priced automobile use(?EB/?Q).Furthermore,in Eq.(13),the first two terms(Q(?CV/?Q)andc2)reflect the marginal cost inside the rail transit system,which can be named the inner-system marginal cost.While the third term captures the marginal effect on non-rail transit users,we can define it as the outer-system marginal cost.Although the sign of social optimal price(pw)is ambiguous,some interesting findings can be found.Firstly,if private cars can be sufficiently charged in congested conditions,the external benefit term from alleviating surface congestion (?EB/?Q)may disappear.In this case,the expression for the socially optimal fare is simplified to only include the innersystem marginalcost,which definitely takesthe positive sign.Furthermore,if the in-vehicle crowding is modest so that the crowding mark-up can be disregarded(i.e.,Q(?CV/?Q)),thesocially optimal fare is well below the average variable costs,resulting in a financial deficit.On the other hand,if the level of crowding is so severe that most passengers have to stand in the crowded coaches,charging the socially optimal fare may generate profit for running the rail transit in densely populated areas.Secondly,if the road congestion cannot be effectively internalized,the more serious the congestion is,the lower the socially optimal price could be.In some extreme cases,under-priced car traffic could lead to rail transit fares being negative.The negative fares mean instead passengers pay for their trips;the transit authority should provide subsidies to encourage private car users to switch their traveling modes.Similarly,the rationality to charge negative transit fares under the second-best condition is also discussed by many transportation economists[10,22,23], implying the robustness of the present result.

    By partially differentiating Eq.(11)with respect to frequency and making it equal to zero,the optimal frequencyfwcan be obtained as:

    From Eq.(14),it is worth noting that if the number of carriages is exogenously given,the optimal frequency follows a modified version of the“square root formula”.More specifically,for the case of low and moderate demand,the first term(Pw/2)in the parentheses dominates over the second term,which indicates that the optimal frequency increases proportionallywith the square rootofdemand.Whereas in the case of higher demand the crowding externality will cause the second term tobe a dominant term,so that the optimal frequency would be approximately proportional to the total demand.As for the massive capacity mode running in high-density corridors,the latter case is more likely to happen than the former one.Thus,the policy recommendation is that when it is impossible to act on the train length,the social optimal reaction to soaring demand is to make the frequency proportional to the total demand,not to the square root of the demand.In what follows,to simplify the expression,we denote ?ρ/?φ as ρφ.Similarly,the optimal number of carriages per train,Nw,can be derived as:

    The ultimate expression for optimal frequency and numberofcarriages can be obtained by simultaneously solving Eqs.(14)and(15),which yields:

    To reflect the total holding capacity of each departure,we introduce a new variable,U,which is the product of service frequency(f)and the number of carriages(N).As a result,by multiplying Eqs.(16)and(17),the total number of carriages per hour can be presented as:

    Substituting Eq.(18)into Eqs.(3)and(4)yields the optimal load factor ΦW.

    3.2.2 Profit maximization optimal results

    Suppose that rail transit services are provided by acommercialmonopolist.Thus,the management objective for this can be presented as:

    Given the profit function in Eq.(21),the firstorder condition with respect to price can be expressed as:

    Through mathematical manipulation,the decision rules for the profit maximizing frequency are given by:

    With the same approach,we can derive the following formulas to obtain the corresponding number of carriages under profit maximization:

    Analogously,simultaneously solving Eqs.(23)and(24)yieldsthedecision ruleforoptimal frequency and numberofcarriagesunderprofit maximization:

    Comparing Eq.(16)with Eq.(25)and Eq.(17)with Eq.(26),we can conclude that in the absence of externality,the decision rules of service provisions are independent on the type of management objectives and keep the same form.But this does not mean the values are identical in these two cases.

    Following the same procedure as before,we can derive the total holding capacity and optimal load factor for profit maximization:

    It is interesting to note that no matter which management objective is pursued,the optimal load factors take the same value,suggesting that the crowding levels are identical in both cases.

    3.3 Comparison of social welfare optima and profit optima

    Clarifying the divergence of profit optima and social welfare optima has received wide attention for many years.It is a standard result that a profitmaximizing monopolist intends to charge a higher fare and offer a lower level of quality than socially desired.Recently,this argument has been challenged by Van Reeven[24].To refute the justification for subsidizing transit arising from Mohring effect,he argued if the operator takes the demand effect of pricing and frequency decisions into consideration,the profit-maximizing monopolist may provide frequency at least as high as the socially optimal frequency.Triggered by this paper,Savage and Small[25]and Basso and Jara-Díaz[26]criticized that Van Reeven’s result isestablished on a very criticaldemand assumption.If this assumption is relaxed,it could give rise to a contrary conclusion.As a reaction to the above criticisms,Karamychev and Van Reeven[27]proposed a rejoinder through generalizing the demand function of Basso and Jara-Diaz[26].

    The compassion for the discrepancy in profit and social welfare maximizing is motivated by this current debate.The novelty of this comparison is that besides discussing the relative magnitude of frequency,the number of carriages and the total holding capacity also enter into comparison picture.

    The preceding analysis clearly shows that the magnitudes of frequency and number of carriages under profit and social welfare maximization are greatly influenced by their corresponding demand.As a result,we first need to compare the relative order of magnitude betweenQπandQW.TheTopkis’s Theorem adopted in the following comparison is:if?SW/?G≥ ?π/?Gand two objective functions,SWand π both have increasing differences,we can conclude that

    To apply Topkis’s theorem,we regard the demand as an endogenous variable and assume that other variables,such as fare,frequency and numbers of carriages are exogenously given.Partially differentiating the social welfare and profitfunctions in Eqs.(12)and(20)with respect to demand yields:

    By subtracting Eq.(30)from Eq.(29)and rearranging some items,we get:

    Since the demand function is concaved with the generalized costs(that is,?Q/?G<0),Eq.(31)takes the positive sign so that we can conclude that?SW/?Q≥ ?π/?Q.

    To fulfill thesecond sufficientcondition of Topkis’s Monotonic Theorem that the objective functions should have increasing differences(ID),we take the cross derivative of the objective functions with respect to the fare as:

    Holding the validity of the two necessary conditions,we can conclude that the social optimal circumstance characterizes a higher demand than the profit maximization case(Qw>Qπ).Based on the above relative relationship,explicit optimum expressions clearly demonstrate that in any case,the number of carriages and total holding capacity per hour are greater for social welfare maximization than for profit maximization.

    Although the relative magnitude for demand,fare and number of carriages is quite clear now,we cannot say whether a profit-maximizing monopolist produces lower or higher frequencies than a social planner does.If the external cost is modest or low,the commercial monopolist would supply frequencies that are less than socially desired.However,if the noise of train vibrations greatly influences residents’lifes,it is possible that the monopolists intend to run more frequent services than the social welfare-maximization operators would do.Accordingly,the consideration of external costs makes the comparison result ambiguous.Since the relative magnitude of frequency between optimal social welfare and profit maximization is theoretically indeterminate,attempts to qualify the relative magnitude will be made through the following empirical case study.

    4 Numerical case studies for Suzhou Rail Transit Line 1

    4.1 General information about Suzhou Rail Transit Line 1

    Conforming to the soaring transport requirement in an urban congested corridor,Suzhou Rail Transit Line 1 was commenced to construct in 2007 and was opened to the public in 2012.As the monopolistic provider,Suzhou Metro Company will retain full responsibility for operating services with freedom to decide levelofservices,fare rates and some necessary investment.Although obtaining the actual patronage and operating cost is impossible before its real operation,the computer-based simulation method can provide relative reliable data and parameters.Here,we will adopt the relevant traffic data and parameters that Suzhou Metro Company used for planning.The notations and values used throughout this paper are summarized in Table 3.

    Table 3 Current operation design and parameter values

    4.2 Specifications of the explicit function form and data calibration

    Following previous modeling,demand function employed is assumed to exponentially depend on generalized cost.

    whereAand λ are parameters assigned to the demand function.Based on this demand function form,the elasticity of demand with respect to the fare is λ·pwith λ being positive.

    In thispaper,the in-vehicle crowding cost function can be explicitly specified as:

    The above non-linear crowding cost function is borrowed from our previous work[28].

    Regarding the noise pollution cost,Zhang[29]analyzed the noise pollution by applying a preventive expenditure approach,his estimation is used here.Additionally,from the social welfare points of view,it is necessary to incorporate the decongestion benefits.Larson[30]proposed a simplified formula to calculate the congestion relief benefits for Oslo’s transit system.Following his work,we constructed a similar function to reflect the marginal benefit as the number of private cars is reduced:

    wheremis the marginal benefit of one addition rail transit passenger,which is the savings of travel time and other externalities due to the removal of car travel.Q0is the ridership in the initial situation.In 2008,Zhu and Zheng[31]estimated the external congestion cost for private car trips in Shanghai.In the absence of empirical research for Suzhou,a crude value from his work was adopted in this paper.

    4.3 Comparisons of four optimal scenarios with designed operation scheme

    Given available estimates of the parameters,it is possible to optimize the fare,frequency,and number of carriages by two scenarios:maximizing social welfare(Scenario 1:MAX-SW)and profit(Scenario 2:MAX-π ). Besides these two management objectives,another more realistic management objective is added,thatis the socialwelfare maximization subject to break even(Scenario 3:MAX-SWB).Relevant results are represented in Table 4.

    The first row of Table 4 presents fare levels.As expected,there exist substantial gaps between current fares and socially optimal ones.During peak times,the severe congestion in the surface road causes the socially preferable fare to be negative(- 0.13 CNY),whereas the socially optimal fare in the offpeak period is extraordinarily small(0.21 CNY).Thus,relative to the current fare levels,the significant price reductions would be socially beneficial.For profit maximization,fares in both periods turn out to be substantially higher than current price levels.Specifically,prices in the peak rise by 200% as compared to a 50%increase in the off-peak period.In the presence of budgetary constraints,the break-even requirementyields fares that are intermediates between the socially optimal value and the one that would be set by a profit maximizing monopolist.Therefore,if the Suzhou Metro Company is only required to cover operating costs and capital costs of rolling stocks,the current fare level is quite high,calling for the substantial reductions.

    The second row of Table 4 depicts the magnitude of frequencies.During the peak period,the value of the socially optimal frequency(13.62 veh/h)is below what is currently offered by the company(20 veh/h),while the optimal frequency provided during the off-peak period is higher than the current operation.As expected,due to the insignificant external noise pollution,the frequency for the profit maximization at any period is well below the socially desired frequency and current operation,which indicates monopolistic operators are intended to under-supply the frequency.Another clear result that emerges from Table 4 is that the imposition of a break-even constraint implies the frequency fell by 35.7 percent in peak time and increased by 14 percentin the off-peak time,compared with frequency in the base case.

    Table 4 Comparison of optimum with current service characteristics

    In regarding the number of carriages,if the rail transit operator is social efficiency orientated,it would prefer to afford more carriages than the commercially monopolistic operator does.This result is in opposition to the conventional view on bus size,that is,the social-welfare maximizing operator has incentive to use smaller buses offering better service frequency.The explanation for this curious result could be that the social-welfare maximizing operator pays some attention to increase consumer surplus using more carriages to reliefovercrowding,while the profit maximizing operator only considers its profit and disregards the intra-marginal user benefits.The typical length of the rail train(4 carriages)currently adopted is relatively short compared to the socially desired ones(that are 5.84 carriages in the peak and 6.76 in the off-peak),but very approximate to the profit maximization of the desired ones.

    If the social welfare is pursued to its absolute maximum(that is the social welfare maximization),the largest social welfare has been achieved at the expense of very high subsidies(30,789 for perk hour and 11,627 CNY for off-perk period),which have substantialfinancialcosts.Comparing the social welfare maximization scenario(Max-SW)with the social welfare maximization subject to the break-even scenario(Max-SWB),it reveals that with the breakeven removed,the improvement in social welfare is relatively small(only 1,716 CNY for one peak hour and 1,191 CNY for one off-peak hour).The consumer surpluses under the current operation arrangements are lowerthan those underthe socialwelfare maximization,and maximizing social welfare is subject to budget constraint due to high charged fares and low service levels(especially for off-peak periods).A practical application of this result is that for a given set of data inputs,the social welfare maximization under the break-even option is preferable and quite acceptable because it yields zero deficits with only a small sacrifice in social welfare.

    5 Conclusions

    By means of a simple line model,this paper deals with jointly optimizing fares,frequency and number of carriages under alternative management objectives.A synthesis of theoretical comparisons and empirical assessment depict the following results:whatever the objective pursued,the resulting optimal decision rules for frequency and number of carriages substantially follow the modified“square root formula”so that the line capacity,defined as the product offrequency and numberofcarriages,proportionally varies with demand.Secondly,in the absence of external costs,the form of decision rules for fare and service provisions are independent on the type of management objectives,while their values are different.Specifically,contrasted with purely profit optimum,social welfare optimum is characterized with lowerfares,greaterfrequency,more numberof carriages and higher ridership.Thirdly,the change from the current operating position to social optimum outputs calls for reducing fares,reducing frequency and adopting more carriages per train.Finally,for the given traffic data and parameters,maximizing social welfare subject to the break-even constraint is an economically and politically preferable objective because it does not need any subsidy with a marginal reduction of social welfare.

    Acknowledgements

    This research was substantially supported by the Ministry of Education(MOE)of Humanities and Social Sciences Project of China(No.12YJA630097).

    [1]van de Velde D.Organizational forms and entrepreneurship in public transport:part 1:classifying organizational forms[J].Transport Policy,1999,6:147-157.

    [2]Vickrey W.Pricing in urban and suburban transport[J]. American EconomicReview, 1963, 53:452-465.

    [3]Mohring H.Optimization and scale economies in urban bus transportation[J].American Economic Review,1972,62:591-604.

    [4]Turvey R,Mohring H.Optimal bus fares[J].Journal ofTransportEconomics and Policy, 1975, 9:280-286.

    [5]Jansson J O.Marginal cost pricing of scheduled transport services[J].Journal of Transport Economics and Policy,1979,13:268-294.

    [6]Jansson J O.A simple bus line model for optimization of frequency and bus size[J].Journal of Transport Economics and Policy,1980,14:53-80.

    [7]Viton P A.Pareto-optimal urban transportation equilibria[J].Research in Transportation Economics,1983,1:75-101.

    [8]Chang S K,Schonfeld P M.Multiple period optimization of bus transit system[J].Transportation Research Part B,1991,25(6):453-478.

    [9]Jara-Diaz S R,Gschwender A.Towards a general microeconomicmodelforthe operation ofpublic transport[J].Transport Reviews,2003,23(4):453-469.

    [10]Small K A.Road pricing and public transport[C].In:Santos G,(Ed.),Road Pricing:Theory and Evidence,Elsevier,Oxford,2004,133-158.

    [11]Tirachini A,Hensher D A,Jara-Díaz S R.Comparing operator and user costs of light rail,heavy rail and bus transit over a radical public transport network[J].Research in Transportation Economics,2010,29(1):231-242.

    [12]Nash C A.Management objectives,fares and service levels in bus transport[J].Journal of Transport Economics and Policy,1978,12:70-85.

    [13]Larsen O I.Marginal cost pricing of scheduled transport services[J].Journal of Transport Economics and Policy,1983,17:315-317.

    [14]Viton P A.The possibility of profitable bus service[J].Journal of Transport Economics and Policy,1980,14:295-314.

    [15]Else P K.Optimal pricing and subsidies for scheduled transport services[J].Journal of Transport Economics and Policy,1985,19(3):263-279.

    [16]Oldfield R H,Bly P H.An analytic investigation of optimal bus size[J].Transportation Research Part B,1988,22(5):319-337.

    [17]Jansson K.Optimal public transport price and service frequency[J].Journal of Transport Economics and Policy,1993,27:33-50.

    [18]Evans A W,Morrison A D.Incorporating accident risk and disruption in economic models of public transport[J].Journal of Transport Economics and Policy,1997,31:117-146.

    [19]Jansson K,Lang H,Mattsson D.Optimal economic interventions in scheduled public transport[J].Research in Transportation Economics,2008,23:30-40.

    [20]Polydoropoulou A,Ben-Akiva M.Combined revealed and stated preference nested Logit access and mode choice model for multiple mass transit technologies[J].Transportation Research Record 1771,TRB,National Research Council, Washington, D.C.,2001,38-45.

    [21]Kraus M.Discomfort externalities and marginal cost transit fares[J].Journal of Urban Economics.1991,29(2):249-259.

    [22]Jansson K.Pricing and financing of the railway in a competitive environment[C].International Conference Series on Competition and Ownership in Land Passenger Transport(THREDBO 6),Cape Town,South Africa,1999.

    [23]Kijung A.Road pricing and bus service policies[J].Journal of Transport Economics and Policy,2009,43(1):25-53.

    [24]Van Reeven P.Subsidisation of urban public transport and the mohring effect[J].Journal of Transport Economics and Policy,2008,42(2):349-359.

    [25]Savage I,Small K A.A comment on 'subsidisation of urban public transport and the mohring effect[J].Journal of Transport Economics and Policy,2010,44(3):373-380.

    [26]Basso L J,Jara-Diaz S R.The case for subsidisation of urban public transport and the Mohring effect[J].Journal of Transport Economics and Policy,2010,44(3):365-372.

    [27]Karamychev V, van Reeven P.Oversupply or undersupply in a public transport monopoly a rejoinder and generalization[J].Journal of Transport Economics and Policy,2010,44(3):381-389.

    [28]Qin F,Jia H.Remodeling in-vehicle crowding cost functionsfor public transit[C]. 75th Annual Transportation Research Board Meeting,Washington,D.C.,2012.

    [29]Zhang G.The analysis of external cost for urban travel modes[D].Master's thesis,Civil and Engineering Department,National Taiwan University,2007.

    [30]Larsen O I.The social optimum public transport model[R].Discussion Paper of Institute of Transport Economics(TOI),2004.

    [31]Zhu C,Zheng W.The analysis of external cost for private car trips in Shanghai[C].In:Proceedings of 16th Symposium on Urban Transportation across the Taiwan Strait,Nanjing,2008.

    中文字幕另类日韩欧美亚洲嫩草| 国产私拍福利视频在线观看| 精品久久久久久久久久免费视频| 成人三级做爰电影| 色综合婷婷激情| 精品午夜福利视频在线观看一区| 很黄的视频免费| 丝袜人妻中文字幕| 母亲3免费完整高清在线观看| 99国产综合亚洲精品| 啦啦啦 在线观看视频| av有码第一页| 女性生殖器流出的白浆| 啦啦啦 在线观看视频| 国产亚洲欧美在线一区二区| 欧美激情极品国产一区二区三区| 国产精品日韩av在线免费观看 | 国产一区二区三区在线臀色熟女| or卡值多少钱| 视频区欧美日本亚洲| 久久精品人人爽人人爽视色| 91精品三级在线观看| 亚洲精品美女久久av网站| 长腿黑丝高跟| 琪琪午夜伦伦电影理论片6080| 亚洲精品国产精品久久久不卡| 变态另类丝袜制服| 90打野战视频偷拍视频| 欧美黑人欧美精品刺激| 久久天堂一区二区三区四区| 日韩欧美三级三区| 国产欧美日韩精品亚洲av| 久久久久久大精品| av在线天堂中文字幕| 日日干狠狠操夜夜爽| 欧美在线一区亚洲| 一个人观看的视频www高清免费观看 | 日韩高清综合在线| 在线观看免费日韩欧美大片| 久久午夜亚洲精品久久| 精品无人区乱码1区二区| 婷婷丁香在线五月| 亚洲精品国产一区二区精华液| 国产片内射在线| 成人18禁高潮啪啪吃奶动态图| 黄色毛片三级朝国网站| 91在线观看av| 香蕉久久夜色| 91在线观看av| 757午夜福利合集在线观看| 亚洲专区国产一区二区| 国产亚洲av高清不卡| 亚洲中文字幕一区二区三区有码在线看 | 亚洲情色 制服丝袜| 成人18禁高潮啪啪吃奶动态图| 日日爽夜夜爽网站| 国产亚洲精品一区二区www| 亚洲国产日韩欧美精品在线观看 | 日韩高清综合在线| videosex国产| 性色av乱码一区二区三区2| a级毛片在线看网站| 久久久久久久久久久久大奶| 高清毛片免费观看视频网站| a在线观看视频网站| 黄片大片在线免费观看| 一区二区三区精品91| 精品熟女少妇八av免费久了| 国产成人欧美在线观看| 久久伊人香网站| 国产aⅴ精品一区二区三区波| 50天的宝宝边吃奶边哭怎么回事| 午夜久久久久精精品| 国产精品电影一区二区三区| 久久 成人 亚洲| 好看av亚洲va欧美ⅴa在| 在线观看舔阴道视频| 两性午夜刺激爽爽歪歪视频在线观看 | 国产精品一区二区在线不卡| 午夜免费鲁丝| 色播在线永久视频| 成年版毛片免费区| 亚洲全国av大片| 村上凉子中文字幕在线| 久久天堂一区二区三区四区| 午夜亚洲福利在线播放| 久久精品国产亚洲av高清一级| 99国产精品一区二区蜜桃av| 1024视频免费在线观看| 好男人在线观看高清免费视频 | 成在线人永久免费视频| 日本a在线网址| 制服诱惑二区| 两人在一起打扑克的视频| 老司机福利观看| 久久久久精品国产欧美久久久| 午夜视频精品福利| 日本免费一区二区三区高清不卡 | 两性夫妻黄色片| 热99re8久久精品国产| 国产精品亚洲av一区麻豆| 丰满人妻熟妇乱又伦精品不卡| 国产1区2区3区精品| 欧美 亚洲 国产 日韩一| 夜夜看夜夜爽夜夜摸| 人人妻,人人澡人人爽秒播| 亚洲第一av免费看| 丰满的人妻完整版| 天堂动漫精品| 精品免费久久久久久久清纯| 久久久久九九精品影院| bbb黄色大片| 免费在线观看亚洲国产| 亚洲国产中文字幕在线视频| 久久热在线av| 一本综合久久免费| 午夜两性在线视频| 波多野结衣高清无吗| av欧美777| 久久精品人人爽人人爽视色| 亚洲精华国产精华精| 波多野结衣一区麻豆| 成年女人毛片免费观看观看9| 精品国产乱子伦一区二区三区| av电影中文网址| 一级黄色大片毛片| 纯流量卡能插随身wifi吗| 亚洲成人精品中文字幕电影| 国产一卡二卡三卡精品| 亚洲av日韩精品久久久久久密| 69av精品久久久久久| 免费在线观看黄色视频的| 日本在线视频免费播放| 一区二区三区国产精品乱码| 在线观看www视频免费| 婷婷六月久久综合丁香| 国产av精品麻豆| 制服诱惑二区| 午夜成年电影在线免费观看| 亚洲精品av麻豆狂野| 亚洲专区国产一区二区| 男女午夜视频在线观看| 99精品欧美一区二区三区四区| 日本a在线网址| x7x7x7水蜜桃| 人人澡人人妻人| 亚洲专区国产一区二区| 亚洲国产精品999在线| 啦啦啦 在线观看视频| 视频在线观看一区二区三区| 性少妇av在线| 久久青草综合色| 国产精品免费视频内射| 亚洲少妇的诱惑av| 老汉色av国产亚洲站长工具| 99国产精品一区二区蜜桃av| aaaaa片日本免费| 人人澡人人妻人| 免费无遮挡裸体视频| 91字幕亚洲| 精品乱码久久久久久99久播| а√天堂www在线а√下载| 国产极品粉嫩免费观看在线| 在线播放国产精品三级| 亚洲一区二区三区不卡视频| 精品电影一区二区在线| 他把我摸到了高潮在线观看| 国产伦人伦偷精品视频| 亚洲人成电影免费在线| 国产日韩一区二区三区精品不卡| 757午夜福利合集在线观看| 久久欧美精品欧美久久欧美| 男女床上黄色一级片免费看| 久久精品国产亚洲av高清一级| 精品熟女少妇八av免费久了| av天堂久久9| 激情在线观看视频在线高清| 国产av在哪里看| 国产一区二区三区综合在线观看| 18美女黄网站色大片免费观看| 成人国语在线视频| 久久国产亚洲av麻豆专区| 精品国产超薄肉色丝袜足j| 两个人免费观看高清视频| 国内毛片毛片毛片毛片毛片| 女警被强在线播放| 精品久久蜜臀av无| 在线观看舔阴道视频| 成人国产一区最新在线观看| 91麻豆精品激情在线观看国产| 搡老妇女老女人老熟妇| 欧美人与性动交α欧美精品济南到| 午夜久久久在线观看| 亚洲专区字幕在线| 久久欧美精品欧美久久欧美| 国产精品,欧美在线| 男女下面插进去视频免费观看| 桃色一区二区三区在线观看| 国产熟女xx| 久久人人97超碰香蕉20202| 亚洲成人国产一区在线观看| av超薄肉色丝袜交足视频| 少妇的丰满在线观看| 婷婷丁香在线五月| 日本免费a在线| 法律面前人人平等表现在哪些方面| netflix在线观看网站| 久久香蕉精品热| 欧美中文日本在线观看视频| 久久久久久久久免费视频了| 丝袜美足系列| 一区二区三区高清视频在线| 亚洲av日韩精品久久久久久密| 日韩有码中文字幕| 日韩大尺度精品在线看网址 | 亚洲av第一区精品v没综合| 97超级碰碰碰精品色视频在线观看| 男男h啪啪无遮挡| 亚洲专区中文字幕在线| 国产午夜精品久久久久久| 香蕉国产在线看| 精品国产乱子伦一区二区三区| 国产一区二区三区视频了| www.999成人在线观看| 午夜精品在线福利| 亚洲欧美日韩高清在线视频| 久久婷婷成人综合色麻豆| 美女高潮到喷水免费观看| 国产精品美女特级片免费视频播放器 | 亚洲中文字幕日韩| 亚洲视频免费观看视频| 一本久久中文字幕| 欧美最黄视频在线播放免费| 日韩精品中文字幕看吧| 午夜影院日韩av| 国产精品一区二区三区四区久久 | 午夜福利18| 久久久久久大精品| 91国产中文字幕| 多毛熟女@视频| 亚洲色图av天堂| 少妇被粗大的猛进出69影院| 亚洲一码二码三码区别大吗| x7x7x7水蜜桃| 午夜日韩欧美国产| 久久久久久免费高清国产稀缺| 日本精品一区二区三区蜜桃| 精品欧美国产一区二区三| 50天的宝宝边吃奶边哭怎么回事| ponron亚洲| 露出奶头的视频| 首页视频小说图片口味搜索| 一级a爱视频在线免费观看| 国产精品二区激情视频| 一进一出抽搐动态| 日韩精品中文字幕看吧| 91av网站免费观看| 波多野结衣巨乳人妻| 18禁国产床啪视频网站| 自拍欧美九色日韩亚洲蝌蚪91| 天天躁夜夜躁狠狠躁躁| 麻豆av在线久日| 国产熟女xx| 变态另类丝袜制服| 日韩欧美国产在线观看| 精品人妻在线不人妻| 日韩一卡2卡3卡4卡2021年| 妹子高潮喷水视频| 99国产精品一区二区蜜桃av| 日韩国内少妇激情av| 国产精品九九99| 黄色丝袜av网址大全| 国产三级在线视频| 精品国产一区二区久久| 国产精品综合久久久久久久免费 | av电影中文网址| 中文字幕人妻丝袜一区二区| 日本在线视频免费播放| 在线观看免费视频网站a站| 极品人妻少妇av视频| 亚洲一区二区三区色噜噜| 99国产精品一区二区蜜桃av| 欧美性长视频在线观看| 国产三级黄色录像| 国产激情欧美一区二区| 美女高潮喷水抽搐中文字幕| www国产在线视频色| 国产精品综合久久久久久久免费 | 中文字幕高清在线视频| 国产黄a三级三级三级人| 色尼玛亚洲综合影院| 国产精品影院久久| 久9热在线精品视频| 亚洲欧美精品综合一区二区三区| 69av精品久久久久久| 香蕉久久夜色| 女生性感内裤真人,穿戴方法视频| 日韩欧美国产在线观看| 一进一出好大好爽视频| 久久久久精品国产欧美久久久| 啦啦啦免费观看视频1| 亚洲欧美激情综合另类| 女人被躁到高潮嗷嗷叫费观| 一本久久中文字幕| 亚洲熟女毛片儿| 久久久久久久精品吃奶| 在线十欧美十亚洲十日本专区| or卡值多少钱| 亚洲av成人一区二区三| 久久久久久久午夜电影| 丁香六月欧美| 国产精品九九99| 欧美一级a爱片免费观看看 | 国产免费av片在线观看野外av| 精品久久蜜臀av无| 村上凉子中文字幕在线| 性少妇av在线| 最好的美女福利视频网| e午夜精品久久久久久久| 女人被躁到高潮嗷嗷叫费观| 99精品久久久久人妻精品| 激情视频va一区二区三区| 一个人观看的视频www高清免费观看 | 国产午夜福利久久久久久| 电影成人av| 岛国在线观看网站| 人成视频在线观看免费观看| 午夜激情av网站| 亚洲aⅴ乱码一区二区在线播放 | 国产亚洲精品一区二区www| 欧美日韩中文字幕国产精品一区二区三区 | 国产亚洲精品一区二区www| 亚洲av日韩精品久久久久久密| 国产精品一区二区免费欧美| 黄片小视频在线播放| 午夜成年电影在线免费观看| 中文字幕人成人乱码亚洲影| 欧美成人免费av一区二区三区| 久久人人精品亚洲av| 亚洲欧美激情综合另类| 午夜免费成人在线视频| 久久久久久亚洲精品国产蜜桃av| 亚洲国产精品999在线| 亚洲色图 男人天堂 中文字幕| 一边摸一边做爽爽视频免费| av超薄肉色丝袜交足视频| 欧美不卡视频在线免费观看 | 19禁男女啪啪无遮挡网站| 午夜免费鲁丝| 国产成年人精品一区二区| 亚洲第一电影网av| 久久狼人影院| 日韩一卡2卡3卡4卡2021年| 午夜精品国产一区二区电影| 99香蕉大伊视频| 麻豆成人av在线观看| 亚洲av电影在线进入| 久久 成人 亚洲| 欧美激情极品国产一区二区三区| 成人精品一区二区免费| 亚洲狠狠婷婷综合久久图片| 韩国av一区二区三区四区| 视频区欧美日本亚洲| 人人澡人人妻人| 亚洲av美国av| 91大片在线观看| 亚洲成人国产一区在线观看| 夜夜躁狠狠躁天天躁| 亚洲男人天堂网一区| 国产精品一区二区免费欧美| 91精品三级在线观看| 人妻丰满熟妇av一区二区三区| 99国产精品免费福利视频| 亚洲在线自拍视频| 欧美激情极品国产一区二区三区| 亚洲av片天天在线观看| 日韩欧美免费精品| 日韩国内少妇激情av| 日本免费a在线| 老司机深夜福利视频在线观看| 叶爱在线成人免费视频播放| 欧美日韩瑟瑟在线播放| 高清黄色对白视频在线免费看| 久久久久国产精品人妻aⅴ院| 51午夜福利影视在线观看| 搡老熟女国产l中国老女人| av在线天堂中文字幕| 50天的宝宝边吃奶边哭怎么回事| 国产精品九九99| 国产99久久九九免费精品| 欧美激情极品国产一区二区三区| 国产av一区在线观看免费| 在线观看免费视频网站a站| 亚洲国产精品久久男人天堂| 久久中文看片网| 精品久久久久久久久久免费视频| 国产三级黄色录像| 韩国av一区二区三区四区| 少妇裸体淫交视频免费看高清 | 操美女的视频在线观看| 无遮挡黄片免费观看| 狂野欧美激情性xxxx| 亚洲国产精品sss在线观看| 色综合欧美亚洲国产小说| 精品一品国产午夜福利视频| 久久午夜综合久久蜜桃| 变态另类丝袜制服| 在线观看舔阴道视频| 国产伦人伦偷精品视频| 国产精品1区2区在线观看.| 日韩大码丰满熟妇| 国产成人欧美| 久久这里只有精品19| 91成人精品电影| 老司机午夜福利在线观看视频| 久久狼人影院| 久久国产精品人妻蜜桃| av有码第一页| 超碰成人久久| 久久精品成人免费网站| 色哟哟哟哟哟哟| 一进一出抽搐动态| 成人三级黄色视频| 日韩欧美在线二视频| 国产高清激情床上av| 日韩欧美国产在线观看| 变态另类丝袜制服| 好看av亚洲va欧美ⅴa在| 久久精品国产亚洲av高清一级| 777久久人妻少妇嫩草av网站| 日韩大码丰满熟妇| 999久久久国产精品视频| 99久久精品国产亚洲精品| 亚洲国产精品sss在线观看| 美女扒开内裤让男人捅视频| 亚洲成人国产一区在线观看| 看片在线看免费视频| 免费看美女性在线毛片视频| 欧美不卡视频在线免费观看 | aaaaa片日本免费| 黄色 视频免费看| 女警被强在线播放| 97人妻精品一区二区三区麻豆 | 九色国产91popny在线| 亚洲精品美女久久av网站| 精品国产国语对白av| 亚洲精品中文字幕一二三四区| 国产精品98久久久久久宅男小说| 精品欧美国产一区二区三| www.自偷自拍.com| 成熟少妇高潮喷水视频| 欧美黄色片欧美黄色片| 丝袜美足系列| cao死你这个sao货| 亚洲中文字幕一区二区三区有码在线看 | 老熟妇乱子伦视频在线观看| 给我免费播放毛片高清在线观看| 97碰自拍视频| 美女扒开内裤让男人捅视频| 亚洲第一av免费看| 伦理电影免费视频| 国产亚洲欧美在线一区二区| 欧美国产精品va在线观看不卡| 麻豆av在线久日| 悠悠久久av| 最新在线观看一区二区三区| 欧美黑人精品巨大| 高潮久久久久久久久久久不卡| 色综合站精品国产| 欧美国产精品va在线观看不卡| a级毛片在线看网站| 亚洲精品在线美女| av片东京热男人的天堂| 男人舔女人下体高潮全视频| 亚洲情色 制服丝袜| 亚洲av电影在线进入| 成人永久免费在线观看视频| 狠狠狠狠99中文字幕| 国产精品99久久99久久久不卡| 欧美成狂野欧美在线观看| av天堂在线播放| 日韩欧美在线二视频| 亚洲男人天堂网一区| 亚洲国产欧美网| 大陆偷拍与自拍| 国产精品99久久99久久久不卡| 日韩av在线大香蕉| 老司机在亚洲福利影院| 真人一进一出gif抽搐免费| 欧美日本亚洲视频在线播放| 国产精品 欧美亚洲| 亚洲熟妇中文字幕五十中出| 国产亚洲精品综合一区在线观看 | 在线天堂中文资源库| 国产熟女xx| 18美女黄网站色大片免费观看| 一进一出抽搐gif免费好疼| 欧美中文日本在线观看视频| 亚洲视频免费观看视频| 精品久久久久久久人妻蜜臀av | 男男h啪啪无遮挡| 亚洲av第一区精品v没综合| 又紧又爽又黄一区二区| 操出白浆在线播放| 99re在线观看精品视频| 精品一区二区三区av网在线观看| 日韩视频一区二区在线观看| 国产精品98久久久久久宅男小说| 99精品久久久久人妻精品| 日韩成人在线观看一区二区三区| 黄色丝袜av网址大全| 久久香蕉国产精品| 欧美日韩瑟瑟在线播放| 香蕉国产在线看| 无遮挡黄片免费观看| 国产高清videossex| 女生性感内裤真人,穿戴方法视频| 好看av亚洲va欧美ⅴa在| 中亚洲国语对白在线视频| 亚洲成人久久性| 非洲黑人性xxxx精品又粗又长| 国产又色又爽无遮挡免费看| 亚洲精品国产色婷婷电影| av有码第一页| 激情在线观看视频在线高清| 丝袜在线中文字幕| 两人在一起打扑克的视频| 久久精品国产清高在天天线| 国产成人精品久久二区二区免费| 亚洲黑人精品在线| 免费在线观看影片大全网站| 十分钟在线观看高清视频www| 色综合亚洲欧美另类图片| 国产1区2区3区精品| 满18在线观看网站| 亚洲专区国产一区二区| 美女 人体艺术 gogo| 一区二区日韩欧美中文字幕| 丁香六月欧美| cao死你这个sao货| 一进一出抽搐gif免费好疼| 精品国产一区二区久久| 午夜免费成人在线视频| 欧美国产日韩亚洲一区| 亚洲av成人av| www日本在线高清视频| 香蕉国产在线看| 无遮挡黄片免费观看| 久久人妻av系列| 亚洲av电影在线进入| 亚洲精品一卡2卡三卡4卡5卡| 国产欧美日韩综合在线一区二区| 男人舔女人下体高潮全视频| 一级毛片精品| 亚洲aⅴ乱码一区二区在线播放 | 天天一区二区日本电影三级 | 日韩欧美国产一区二区入口| 成人18禁在线播放| 国产成人精品在线电影| 国产精品99久久99久久久不卡| 三级毛片av免费| 久久婷婷人人爽人人干人人爱 | cao死你这个sao货| 老熟妇仑乱视频hdxx| 精品日产1卡2卡| АⅤ资源中文在线天堂| 日韩精品中文字幕看吧| 精品熟女少妇八av免费久了| av欧美777| 真人做人爱边吃奶动态| 日韩av在线大香蕉| 精品电影一区二区在线| 日韩欧美在线二视频| videosex国产| 午夜激情av网站| 久久久精品国产亚洲av高清涩受| 国产又色又爽无遮挡免费看| 丁香六月欧美| 亚洲五月天丁香| 国产精品影院久久| 亚洲男人的天堂狠狠| 欧美激情极品国产一区二区三区| 国产精品1区2区在线观看.| 可以在线观看的亚洲视频| 久热这里只有精品99| 韩国av一区二区三区四区| 如日韩欧美国产精品一区二区三区| 欧美在线黄色| 免费一级毛片在线播放高清视频 | 18禁观看日本| 高清在线国产一区| 日本免费a在线| 纯流量卡能插随身wifi吗| 国产片内射在线| 午夜亚洲福利在线播放| 国产欧美日韩一区二区三区在线| 久久伊人香网站| 91av网站免费观看| 国产欧美日韩一区二区三区在线| 亚洲精品国产色婷婷电影| 制服丝袜大香蕉在线| 日本免费一区二区三区高清不卡 | 亚洲熟妇中文字幕五十中出| 色老头精品视频在线观看| 一区在线观看完整版| 欧美黑人精品巨大| 亚洲午夜理论影院| 高清毛片免费观看视频网站| 午夜影院日韩av| 精品国产乱子伦一区二区三区| 亚洲国产精品成人综合色| 乱人伦中国视频| 91大片在线观看| 亚洲欧美一区二区三区黑人| 18禁观看日本|