• <tr id="yyy80"></tr>
  • <sup id="yyy80"></sup>
  • <tfoot id="yyy80"><noscript id="yyy80"></noscript></tfoot>
  • 99热精品在线国产_美女午夜性视频免费_国产精品国产高清国产av_av欧美777_自拍偷自拍亚洲精品老妇_亚洲熟女精品中文字幕_www日本黄色视频网_国产精品野战在线观看 ?

    Private Benefits of Control, Growth Opportunities and Investor Protection*

    2009-04-05 17:30:56MinXiondJixingYou
    China Journal of Accounting Research 2009年1期
    關(guān)鍵詞:理工類專業(yè)英語英語教學(xué)

    Min Xiond Jixing You**

    aSchool of Management, Xiamen University, China

    bSchool of Economics, Xiamen University, China

    Private Benefits of Control, Growth Opportunities and Investor Protection*

    Min Xiaoaand Jiaxing Youb,**

    aSchool of Management, Xiamen University, China

    bSchool of Economics, Xiamen University, China

    We develop a model to illustrate that controlling shareholders choose the level of investor protection that maximizes their own interests. Controlling shareholders in companies with complicated control structures can easily extract private benefits and are thus reluctant to enhance investor protection which would necessitate increased transparency. In contrast, controlling shareholders in companies with valuable growth opportunities are willing to improve investor protection so that they can benefit from the increased value resulting from the lower cost of capital. We test this prediction using firm-level data in China. The results show that the level of investor protection increases with decreases in control structure opacity and increases in growth opportunities. The correlation is more significant for enforcement than for the mechanisms of investor protection.

    JEL classification: G30; K22

    Private benefits of control; Growth opportunities; Investor protection

    1. Introduction

    Since La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Schleifer, and Vishny (abbreviated hereafter as“LLSV”) established the “l(fā)aw and finance” field in 1998, both academic and practical approaches to corporate governance have increasingly focused on the problem of the legal protection of minority shareholders against expropriation by corporate insiders. Many studies focus on the consequences of investor protection and find that legal protection for investors is associated with many corporate financial issues, such as ownership structure (LLSV, 1999), dividend policy (LLSV, 2000), cost of capital (Himmelberg et al., 2002), and equity valuation ( LLSV, 2002). As the index of investor protection constructed by LLSV is computed at the country level, related empirical studies use either cross-country analysis (eg, LLSV, 2000) or time-series analysis (eg, Shen et al., 2004). By doing so they imply two assumptions: that firms in a single legal regime are homogenous in their practice of investor protection, and that firm-level investor protection is exogenously determined by laws and regulations.1In the law and finance literature, investor protection is the legal protection of minority shareholders and creditors against expropriation by corporate insiders. In this paper, unless otherwise noted, “investor” is defined as a minority shareholder of a listed company and “protection” is defined as firm-level mechanism and its enforcement.

    In contrast to these country-level studies, Duenev and Kim (2005) find wide withincountry variation in governance and disclosure practices, with the variation increasing as the legal environment becomes less investor friendly. Consistent with Coase (1960), such within-country variation reflects firms’ adaptation to poor legal environments. Firms with better investment opportunities, a greater need for external financing or more concentrated ownership undertake better corporate governance and disclosure.

    Based on the Coase theorem, Bergman and Nicolaievslay (2007) suggest that absent a strong legal regime, capital suppliers and users should negotiate, agree, and privately contract on the efficient level of investor protection. Thus, firms can contractually “opt out” of the law. They find that due to a weak legal regime in Mexico, the ability to enforce “precisely filtering contracts” is relatively weak, and only “imprecisely filtering contracts” can be well enforced.2In the Bergman and Nicolaievslay (2007) study, “precisely filtering contracts” provide protection to investors only when it is necessary: ie, in the eventualities that expropriation can occur, and only in these eventualities. Precisely filtering contracts, therefore, bar expropriation without barring firms from performing other possibly efficient actions. On the contrary, “imprecisely filtering contract” can only bar a kind of action with possible expropriation, ie, connected party transaction, without distinguishing the essentiality in investor protection.As a result, the legal protection offered to investors may induce an over-regulation cost while preventing expropriation or inefficiency. In this case, private firms tend to offer contracts that are over-inclusive because of low renegotiation costs, whereas public firms tend to offer contracts that are under-inclusive because of high renegotiate costs. Recently La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Schleifer recognized in their new work with Djankov that prior studies have not distinguisheddefault rules, mandatory rules, and enabling provisions in the law. Firms can opt out of default rules and enabling provisions or enhance investor protection by including provisions favorable to shareholders in their charters (Djankov et al., 2008).

    The stock market in the People’s Republic of China was established at the beginning of 1990s, followed by the gradual development of the legal framework for investor protection. The Company Law and Securities Law, which are the core of the legal framework that protects investors, were revised in 2005, with effect from 2006. Driven by this development of a legal framework, Chinese listed companies have implemented investor protection mechanisms. In the Chinese legal system, there are mandatory rules, default rules, and enabling provisions. Compared to criminal law, the commercial law that regulates investor protection tends to include more default rules and enabling provisions. One of the important emendations of the revised Company Law is “taking the spirit of company self-regulation, considering the space of participants’ negotiation, and extending the application of non-mandatory rules greatly.” (Luo, 2007). Data from the Self-Evaluation Report and Rectification Plan on Corporate Governance (abbreviated as “Self-Evaluation Report” hereafter) provided by Chinese listed companies show that there is wide firm-level variation in the mechanisms of investor protection, especially in enforcement provisions (Shen et al., 2009).

    Although the law and finance literature focuses on country-level variation and implicitly assumes firm-level investor protection to be exogenous, it seems reasonable in both theoretical and practical terms that the firm-level legal protection of investors may be not only heterogeneous but also endogenous even under identical legal environments. If that is the case, why do different firms choose different levels of investor protection? An exploration offirm-level investor protection and its determinants will thus be able to shed significant light on the protection of investors.

    The extent of firm-level investor protection is likely to depend heavily on microlevel individual contracting in a given legal system within the context of relevant laws. We thus present a simple model based on the heterogeneous and exogenous nature of firm-level investor protection which suggests that favorable legal protection for investors is determined by company attributes in a given legal environment. Controlling shareholders perform a trade-off between the gains and losses induced by investor protection to maximize their own interests. The benefits of controlling shareholders can be categorized as the private benefit of control and the shared benefit of the entire equity (Holderness, 2003). Investor protection restrains the private benefit of control by increasing the cost of theft and improves the shared benefit by lowering the cost of capital and increasing the ability to finance profitable investment opportunities (LLSV, 2002; Dyck and Zingales, 2004; Himmelberg et al., 2002; Demirgü?-Kunt and Maksimovic, 1998). To maximize their own total benefit, controlling shareholders choose the optimal level of investor protection. We use a set of firm-level indices for investor protection based on the Self-Evaluation Report and empirically test the relationship between investor protection, private benefits of control, and investment opportunities.

    The remainder of this paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents the theoretical model. Section 3 introduces the institutional background in China. Section 4 elaborates hypotheses based on the theoretical model and the institutional background. Section 5 describes the data and variables. Section 6 tests the relationship between investor protection, private benefits of control, and investment opportunities. Section 7 concludes the paper.

    2. Theoretical Model

    Following LLSV (2002) and Doidge et al. (2004), we present a single-period model of an all-equity firm that is fully controlled by a single shareholder. To illustrate the tradeoffthat determines the level of investor protection, we assume that the controlling shareholder has an exogenously determined cash flow or equity ownership of k in the firm. If there is no expropriation, the firm will receive an amount of Cash C at the end of the period to be shared by all shareholders. However, not all of the cash flow is distributed to shareholders on a pro rata basis. As a benefit of controlling the firm, the controlling shareholder diverts a share f of the firm’s cash flow C to himself before distributing the rest as dividends, given that his ownership is less than 100%. Stealing is not free: c is the cost of theft. Under a pyramid or cross-holding ownership arrangement, the control structure of the controlling shareholder is complicated and stealing is concealed by layers of the control chain and the separation of control rights and cash flow rights. An investor protection system, in contrast, makes it difficult for a controlling shareholder to steal. We use o to indicate the level of concealment of the control structure and p to indicate the level of investor protection. The cost of theft c is related to the level of expropriation f. The marginal cost of stealing is positive, and rises as more is stolen: ie, cf>0 and cff>0. Stealing is easier with a more complicated control structure and costlier with more protective legal regime: that is, co<0, cp>0. To simplify the analysis, we assume that the cost of theft has a simple functional form that is quadratic in f and linearly increasing in p as in line with LLSV (2002) and Doidge et al. (2004): ie,

    (where b is a constant). Under these assumptions, the controlling shareholder receives

    where the first term is the controlling shareholder’s share of after-theft cash flow (the shared benefit) and the remaining two terms are his net benefits from expropriation (the private benefit of control).

    Then, the controlling shareholder chooses f, solving the following maximization problem. The first order condition for this problem is given by

    which can be rewritten as

    We substitute (3) into original maximization problem (1) and obtain the total gain of the controlling shareholder,

    A higher level of investor protection pHhelps to enhance the confidence of outside investors, lower the cost of capital, and facilitate external financing. The cash flow of the company is thereby improved by z (z>0) through the increase in its ability to take advantage of valuable growth opportunities. Following Doidge et al. (2004), for simplicity we assume that if the investor protection is only p, the firm cannot gain access to sufficient financing and take advantage of these growth opportunities. When the level of investor protection is improved to pH, the firm is able to fund profitable opportunities and obtain the cash flow (C+z) at the end of the period. As growth opportunities increase, so does z. Both the minority shareholders and the controlling shareholder can share (C+z). The controlling shareholder, nevertheless, notices that higher-level investor protection pHalso means the complicated control structure will be discovered or will have to be rearranged. Assuming that the level of the concealment of the control structure is reduced into (o-x), the cost of theft increases and the private benefit of control decreases. Given the change of cash flow, the level of concealment of the control structure and the cost of theft, the controlling shareholder must resolve his problem. Under the assumption of higher investor protection pH, at the end of the period the cash flowing to the controlling shareholder is

    To have the partial derivative:

    For second derivative,

    Therefore, the controlling shareholder chooses the level of investor protection to maximize his net gains. Other things being equal, controlling shareholders in firms with simpler and more transparent control structures have limited opportunities to steal so that their private benefit of control is not reduced very much by improvements in investor protection. Controlling shareholders in firms with more complicated control structures stand to see their private benefit of control significantly eroded, and thus they tend not to improve investor protection. In firms with more profitable investment opportunities and more external financing needs, improvements in investor protection lower the cost of capital needed to fund investment opportunities and increase the shared benefit greatly. Controlling shareholders in these firms thus tend to improve investor protection. In firms with few growth opportunities, however, improvements in investor protection cannot increase the shared benefit significantly through a lower cost of capital and higher equity value. In this instance, controlling shareholders have less incentive to improve investor protection. To summarize, other things being equal, controlling shareholders tend to choose to protect outside shareholders better when the control structure is transparent or growth opportunities are better. In the firms with both control structure opacity and growth potential, controlling shareholders trade offthe losses and gains that will result from improvements in investor protection and decide on a moderate level of such protection to maximize their net gains.

    3. Institutional Background

    3.1. Stock Market and Corporate Governance in China

    The stock market in the People’s Republic China was established as part of an ongoing series of reforms. In 1984, the Chinese government shifted the focus of its reform of the economic system from the countryside to the cities, at the same time launching pilot projects to determine the feasibility of share economy. These pilot projects began with collective enterprises and small state-owned businesses and were then extended to small and medium-sized state-owned enterprises, and finally to large state-owned enterprises.

    The initial form of the stock market in China was an over-the-counter transaction market launched in Shanghai during 1986, followed by the establishment of the Shanghai Stock Exchange in December 1990 and the Shenzhen Stock Exchange in June 1991.

    Emerging as part of a reform process centered on state-owned enterprises, Chinese listed firms are quite different from their peers in developed markets. The equity of thesecompanies is spilt into public shares, legal person shares, and state-owned shares. Public shares are generally held by outside minority investors and are tradable on the stock exchange. Legal person shares and state-owned shares, which are generally held by the firm’s promoter, cannot be transferred freely on the exchange. Holders of non-tradable shares who control a firm are not consistent with outside minority shareholders in interests, which blocks the alignment effect of shareholding. In addition, a typical listed firm in China has been spun off from a state-owned enterprise and restructured. Its connection with its controlling shareholders thus facilitates an entrenchment effect.

    With the development of the Chinese capital market, the ultimate owners of listed companies have become diversified, and include the State-owned Assets Supervision and Administration Commission (SASAC) representing the central or local government, state-owned enterprises, and private individuals. There are considerable differences in acquirement of resources, control structure, and corporate governance between companies controlled by state-owned and non-state-owned entities. What should be noted particularly are those firms ultimately owned by local government and those owned by private individuals.

    In the process of the Chinese government’s economic reforms, local governments have acquired increasing power to allocate resources, which gives them the incentive to compete with their peers. With the strict control of the approval procedure, company listing has become a kind of scarce resource. Local governments compete in terms of access to the stock market by helping the companies they control to list. The companies subsequently listed are expected to support the regional economy. Given poor property protection and ineffective supervision mechanisms, corruption and rent-seeking thus arise to a certain extent. Under these circumstances, minority shareholders are likely to be exposed to expropriation.

    Compared with stated-owned enterprises, listed firms controlled by private individuals are in an inferior position. It is difficult for them to acquire financing due to their small size, weak managerial systems and disadvantageous social capital. Perhaps due to the financial restraint, these companies typically have more complicated ownership structures, such as pyramids or cross-holdings. The separation of control rights and cash flow rights prevails in these companies, which also threaten the interests of minority shareholders even though the ultimate owners are less powerful than in state-owned enterprises.

    3.2. Investor Protection Regulations in China

    With the development of the stock market, the Regulation on Pilot Project of Shareholding System and the Regulation on Listed Companies were published in 1992. The regulations emphasize “one share, one vote” and stipulate various rights for shareholders. In the same year, the China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) was founded. In April 1993, the State Council issued its Provisional Regulations on the Administration of Share Issuance and Trading, which were the first comprehensiveregulations on stock issuance and exchange in the People’s Republic of China.

    To meet the demand for the development of a modern enterprise system, the Company Law was formally promulgated and came into force in July 1994. The law aimed at regulating firms’ operations to protect the legal rights and interests of their shareholders and creditors. It was the first national commercial law in the People’s Republic of China to include and included all of the important items on investor protection from prior regulations. In 1997, the Securities Law came into force, adjusting and supplementing some aspects of investor protection based on prior regulations and emphasizing the principles of openness, fairness, and impartiality in security issuance and dealing.

    The Company Law and Securities Law laid a foundation for the legal system in the Chinese stock market. Following Western legislative experiences for reference, the Chinese government formulated or revised a number of other laws and regulations.Thus, a relatively complete system of investor protection was constructed in a short time. To meet the needs of the developing market, the two laws were revised in 2005. The new Company Law reflects the spirit of respecting the market mechanism and company self-regulation instead of over-regulation; it strengthens corporate governance and shareholder protection. The new Securities Law requires that intermediaries operate in the prescribed manner, defines the legal liability of civil affairs related to securities, and stipulates more severe punishment for those who violate the law.

    在這一背景下,本研究著手對理工類院校ESP課程需求進行調(diào)查分析,以為下一步的大學(xué)英語教學(xué)改革提供實證支撐。本研究的開展主要基于以下兩點認識:首先是理工類學(xué)生的專業(yè)性強,其專業(yè)英語與EGP教學(xué)內(nèi)容差別更大,因而他們的ESP需求更具代表性;其次是根據(jù)需求理論,需求分析是系統(tǒng)化的教學(xué)課程改革建設(shè)中不可缺少的一環(huán),其重要性包含課程改革的所有方面,而國內(nèi)目前的需求分析主要著眼于高職院校學(xué)生的ESP需求分析,對普通高校,尤其是理工類院校學(xué)生的ESP需求調(diào)查則嚴重缺乏。

    3.3. Enforcement of Investor Protection in China

    Compared with the rapid development of the legal framework for investor protection, the enforcement environment has been a more difficult scenario. In the traditionally poor legal environment, the rules of investor protection have not sufficiently taken effect. Although the early chaos of the securities market has been eliminated, the expropriation of minority shareholder interest has not been abolished.

    In principle, civil liability, administrative liability and criminal liability exist to deter breaches of the law in relation to investor protection. Administrative liability is heavily emphasized in China, and criminal liability is infrequently triggered for securities issues. Civil liability, aimed at defending the civil rights and interests of victims, was incurred late in 2002, but difficulties remain in that area even today.

    Investor protection is enforced in two ways: administratively by the CSRC and legally through the local court system. Generally, the prosecution, investigation, punishment, and education conducted by the CSRC and its subsidiaries play an important role in deterring illegality and protecting minority shareholders. In contrast, legal redress is not effective. It is difficult for local courts to retain their independence because of their personnel and financial reliance on local governments.The courts are open to government intervention and regional protectionism prevails in judicial practice, which increases the cost of law suits brought by minority shareholders.

    3.4. Non-tradable Shares Reform and Overall Listing Program

    To solve the institutional problem of split ownership, the Chinese government launched the Non-tradable Share Reform in May 2005. Non-tradable shareholders pay some “consideration” to tradable shareholders to exchange the rights of shares trading so that all the shares have equal rights. At the same time, the government began to promote an Overall Listing Program that required listed companies to stay independent of their controlling shareholders. A company that is about to go public should avoid spin offs in the listing process, and a company that has listed should try to acquire its parent company. All listed companies are expected to be integrated and independent after the program so that the controlling shareholders’ motivation to expropriate is limited. Undoubtedly, the Non-tradable Share Reform and the Overall Listing Program together strengthen the alignment effect and mitigate the entrenchment effect of shareholding in Chinese listed companies.

    4. Research Hypotheses

    As discussed in the previous section, the legal protection of investors is well developed but the environment of enforcement is lagging in China. At present, the enforcement of investor protection is relative weak and public administration is stronger than the legal system. Nevertheless, the expropriation of minority shareholders by insiders is being held back to some extent by the Non-tradable Share Reform and the Overall Listing Program, and the environment is in the process of improving.

    Unlike in developed market economies with strong legal systems, there is wide within-country variation in the Chinese stock market because of differences in growth opportunities, control structures and investor protection for different companies. This variation enables us to study the firm-level determinants of investor protection within one country. Firms with more complicated control structures tend to protect the private control benefit instead of the interests of minority shareholders. Firms with more growth opportunities tend to increase the level of investor protection to lower the cost of capital and fund profitable opportunities. Unlike in underdeveloped market economies with extremely poor legal systems, investors in China do not disregard the investor protection offered by companies. If the legal system does not work at all, the individual contract is meaningless. In this circumstance, investor protection can neither increase the cost of theft nor lower the cost of capital by changing the expectations of minority investors. In China, the effect of legal protection on investors is limited by a weak legal environment to some extent, but it is not impossible for companies to become creditable to outside investors through well-enforced investor protection.

    It is obviously not sufficient for listed companies to simply set up investor protection mechanisms. Only when those mechanisms are put into practice can they be trusted by minority shareholders, which decreases the cost of capital. Overall, the relationshipbetween private control benefits, growth opportunities, and investor protection predicted by our theoretical model should be tenable in China. However, it should be noted that what really works in the relationship may be the enforcement instead of the mechanisms of investor protection.

    H1. The level of investor protection is negatively related to the opacity of the control structure, with the correlation more significant for enforcement than for the mechanisms of investor protection under a relatively weak legal environment.

    H2. The level of investor protection is positively related to growth opportunities, with the correlation more significant for enforcement than for the mechanisms of investor protection under a relatively weak legal environment.

    H3. More growth opportunities help to mitigate the negative correction between the level of investor protection and the opacity of control structure, with the influence more significant for enforcement than for the mechanisms of investor protection under a relatively weak legal environment.

    5. Data and Variables

    5.1. Data

    To meet the requirements of the Note for Special Activities on Enhancing the Governance Structure of Listed Companies (CSRC, companies, [2007]28), all companies listed on the Shanghai and Shenzhen stock exchanges are required to evaluate corporate governance by themselves according to related laws and regulations. By November 14, 2007, 1,432 companies had completed Self-Evaluation Reports. In the questionnaire on which the Report is based, the CSRC asks 100 questions on corporate governance, of which 22 are directly related to the legal protection offered to minority shareholders. Replies to these questions provide valuable data for firm-level investor protection research. Given the importance placed on the survey by the CSRC, exchanges, and listed companies, it generates a much better response rate and better response quality than a typical questionnaire (Shen et al. 2009). It also provides the first and most comprehensive dataset of cross-sectional investor protection information of Chinese listed companies in a uniform format.

    Following Shen et al. (2009), we hand-collected the data on control right structures and investor protection from completed Self-Evaluation Reports, and obtained financial and other data from the Wind database. To avoid bias in the research, we exclude the following: (1) firms with missing data in the Wind database; (2) firms listed after the end of 2006; (3) firms with missing information in the Self-Evaluation Report; (4) financialcompanies such as banks; (5) firms with extreme values out of the 1st-99th percentile of the variable distribution. We thus obtained 1029 sample companies (Table 1).

    5.2. Variables

    5.2.1. Dependant Variable: Investor Protection

    The investor protection proposed by LLSV (1998) is described by legal origin and three measures, including shareholder rights, creditor rights, and enforcement. For shareholder protection, because shareholders exercise their power by voting for directors and voting on major corporate issues, LLSV focus on voting procedures in evaluating shareholder rights. Those rights encompass the “one share, one vote” principle, the“anti-director rights”, and the “bright-line rule”, which reflects the right to a mandatory dividend. Anti-director rights cover the following six areas: (1) voting by mail; (2) obstacles to the actual exercise of the right to vote; (3) minority representation on the board of directors through cumulative voting or proportional representation; (4) an oppressed minority mechanism to seek redress in case of expropriation; (5) preemptive rights to subscribe to new securities issues by the company; and (6) the right to call a special shareholder meeting. Djankov et al. (2008) revised the anti-director rights index by associating better investor protection with laws that are explicitly mandated, or set as default rules, provisions that are favorable to minority shareholders. They revised index by retreating the enabling provisions while keeping the core of the six sub-indices.

    For enforcement, LLSV (1998) use five measures: efficiency of the judicial system, rule of law, corruption, risk of expropriation by the government, and likelihood of contract repudiation by the government. In addition, because accounting plays a potentially crucial role in corporate governance, they use an estimate of the quality of the country’s accounting standards. Djankov et al. (2008) present a new and more direct measure of investor protection, the anti-self-dealing index, to reflect the legal protection of minority shareholders against self-interested related-party transactions. They describe a hypothetical self-dealing transaction and gathered from attorneys to survey in detail how each country’s legal system regulates that transaction. The new measures include private enforcement and public enforcement, where private enforcement is divided intoex-ante and post-private control of self-dealing.

    Following LLSV (1998), Shen et al. (2004) construct a Chinese time series investorprotection regulation index to investigate investor protection within one country. They focus on 16 items associated with shareholder rights and other regulations of investor protection, and develop the index based on the Key Laws and Regulations Index in the Guide for Investor Protection Education issued by the CSRC. Jiang et al. (2008) develop a Chinese firm-level investor protection index using the Delphi method. They ask experts from both academic and practical area to determine the main items of investor protection and their weight. Considering the quality offinancial reports, related-party transaction, the amount of grabbing by controlling shareholders, profitability, market return, potential profitability, cash dividend, return of holding stocks, punishment by the CSRC, and criticism of the company by the CSRC or the exchanges, the indices include five measures: the right to know, the right to share benefits equally, maximization of shareholder wealth, return on investment, and honesty of the company. Different from a typical investor protection index, this index is constructed from the perspective of all investors, rather than minority shareholders.

    Macro-level analysis, such as cross-country measures and time series indices of legal protection, might not be adequate for firm-level research. It is not easy to control other macro-level variables and distinguish the difference among individual companies when doing so. Although Jiang et al. (2008) make an effort to solve this problem their index is too comprehensive for use with corporate governance. In line with LLSV (1998), Shen et al. (2004), and Djankov et al. (2008), Shen et al. (2009) develop a Chinese firm-level investor protection index by filtering and classifying the replies associated with investor protection from the Self-Evaluation Report. However, of the 22 questions associated with investor protection in the Self-Evaluation Report, only 6, 7, 8, 4 companies replied with “No” for “violating the Rule on Shareholder’s Meeting of Listed Companies”,“insider control”, “information leaks,” and “insider trading,” respectively. The percentage of negative answers was too low (less than 1%) to be included in computing the index. Hence, we revised the index developed by Shen et al. (2009) by using the answers to the remaining 18 questions to obtain our investor protection composite index, IP_Comp (Table 2).3To avoid possible bias, we still considered the answers to all 22 questions in the robustness test. Please see Shen et al. (2009) for detailed statistics information about of each item included in the investor protection index.

    In China, legal rules of investor protection have been regulated gradually with the development of the stock market. However, enforcement improvement is lagging. In this context, it may be difficult, if not impossible, for the investor protection mechanisms established by firms to be put into practice. Only when investor protection is brought into effect can firms restrain insider expropriation and obtain the trust of outside investors. We thus break the investor protection composite index IP_Comp into three: IP_Anti is an anti-director index, IP_Disc is a disclosure index, and IP_Enfo is an enforcement index of investor protection (Table 2).

    5.2.2. Independent Variables: Control Structure and Growth Opportunities

    Following the methodology of Claessens et al. (2000), we hand-collected data on ultimate ownership held by controlling shareholders by tracing the pyramid and crossholding control chains disclosed in the Self-Evaluation Report. We define control rights (C) as minimal ownership in the control chain and cash flow rights (O) as the product of the percentage in the control chain of the controlling shareholder (or the sum of the product, if there is more than one control chain for that shareholder). We then have the separation of control rights and cash flow rights, C_O. Layer measures the number of layers in the control chain of the controlling shareholder. For instance, the Layer is 1 if B directly controls listed firm A and 2 if B controls A through C.

    Tobin’s Q, market-book value ratio and sales growth are often used to measure growth opportunities. However, Tobin’s Q and the market-book value ratio are not adequate here because not all shares of Chinese listed firms were tradable before the end of 2006. We thus use the average annual sales growth rate in 2004-2006 as the proxy for the investment opportunity set, Inv_Oppo. As the rate of sales growth increases, so do a firm’s investment opportunities. In addition, following Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic (1998) and Durnev and Kim (2005), we estimate the external finance needed for growth, Ext_Fin, as the difference between the firm’s actual growth rate and internal growth rate. The actual growth rate is computed as a two-year average of the annual growth rate of total assets in 2005-2006, and the internal growth rate as a two-year average of (ROA×b)/(1-ROA×b).6See Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic (1998; p. 2111) for an elaboration of this measure. In our paper, Ext_Fin = actual growth rate - internal growth rate. In the formula for the internal growth rate, b is the proportion of the firm’s earnings retained for reinvestment. To avoid the influence of outliers, we set the actual growth rate as 1 when it is more than 1.We assume that those firms with higher Ext_Fin have more investment opportunities and need more outside capital given internal financial resources.

    5.2.3. Control Variables

    We control firm size, leverage, and the cash flow rights of the ultimate owner. Considering the relatively poor legal environment, prevailing government administrationand the difference among firms with different controlling shareholders in control structure, the ability to finance and corporate governance in China, we divide our sample into four parts: firms controlled by private individuals, firms controlled by stateowned enterprises, firms controlled by local government, and firms controlled by the central government. We use three dummies to control this difference: Corporation, Local_Gov, and Center_Gov (Table 3).

    5.3. Descriptive Statistics and Correlation Analysis

    The descriptive statistics in Table 4 show that the investor protection composite index is from 5 to 16 with an average of 11.256. Specifically, the anti-director index, disclosure index, and enforcement index are distributed as [0, 5], [0, 2], and [2, 10], respectively. There is enough variation in the investor protection composite index, antidirector index and enforcement index. In unreported descriptive statistics, all of the kurtosis and the skewness for these indices are close to zero. The disclosure indices for different companies are slightly similar, which may have some negative influence on the following regression.

    The correlation analysis in Table 5 shows that the investor protection composite index correlates with the anti-director index, the disclosure index, and the enforcement index at 53%, 28%, and 84%, respectively. It also correlates significantly with the four explanatory variables, ie, control layers, the separation of control and cash flow rights, investment opportunities, and external funding needs, at -6%, -6%, 19% and 18%, respectively. Specifically, the correlation of the enforcement index with the explanatory variables is more significant than those of the anti-director index and disclosure index. Our hypotheses are preliminarily supported by the correlation analysis.

    6. Empirical Test and Results

    6.1. Relation between Control Structure and Investor Protection

    In this section we turn to the regression analysis. To examine the relation between control structure and investor protection, we use all four indices of investor protection (IP_Comp, IP_Anti, IP_Disc, and IP_Enfo) as dependent variables and Layer and C_O as independent variables. The regression in Table 6 shows that the investor protection composite index, IP_Comp, is significantly negatively related to Layer and C_O. Generally, the level of investor protection is lower for companies with more complicated control structures. However, the significantly negative relation between investor protection and control structure exists only for the enforcement index and not for the anti-director and disclosure indices. Therefore, our results are supportive of H1. Control structure opacity facilitates the acquirement of private benefit of control and discourages the improvement of investor protection. In China, the negative correlation is more likely to exist for the quality of enforcement than for the establishment of mechanisms of investor protection due to the relatively weak legal environment.

    6.2. Growth Opportunities and Investor Protection

    Using the indices of investor protection (IP_Comp, IP_Anti, IP_Disc, and IP_Enfo) as dependent variables and the investment opportunities set (Inv_Oppo) and external funding needs (Ext_Fin) as independent variables, we estimate a regression to explore the relation between growth opportunities and investor protection.

    The regression results in Table 7 indicate that the investor protection composite index increases significantly with both investment opportunities and external funding needs. Specifically, this relation exists for the anti-director index and the enforcement index rather than the disclosure index. The results thus support H2. More investment opportunities and more outside capital are needed motivate the controlling shareholder to protect investors better so that the company can finance profitable opportunities with a lower cost of capital. In this way, the controlling shareholder can obtain more shared benefit. Given the relatively ineffective legal institutions in China, the positivecorrelation between growth opportunities and investor protection is more likely to exist for the quality of enforcement than for the establishment of mechanisms of investor protection.

    6.3. Control Structure, Growth Opportunities, and Investor Protection

    Given that the level of investor protection decreases with the opacity of the control structure and increases with growth opportunities, how would investor protection fare if the two determinants combined? To consider this situation we introduce the interaction terms of control structure and growth opportunities into the regression. In the left sides of Tables 8 and 9, the results reveal that the coefficients of Layer are negative and those of the interaction terms of Layer and Inv_Oppo and Layer and Ext_Fin are positive. All are statistically significant except in the regression of the anti-director index and the disclosure index. The right sides of Tables 8 and 9 show that except for the anti-director index, the level of investor protection increases with the decrease in C_O and with the interaction term of C_O and growth opportunities. However, only the coefficients in the regression of the investor protection composite index and the enforcement index are all statistically significant. These results are supportive of H3. More growth opportunities help to mitigate the negative correlation between the opacity of the control structure and the level of investor protection, but the effect is associated more with enforcement rather than the mechanisms of investor protection.

    6.4. Robustness Test

    To examine the robustness of the abovementioned results, we reconsider the investor protection index by eliminating the items with some ambiguity in computing the antidirector index, keeping the four items with little variation in the enforcement index and combining the anti-director and disclosure indices into an establishment index. Using these new indices, our main results remain unchanged.

    In addition, we replace the average annual sales growth rate and external funding needs with the market-book value of equity in 2006 as a proxy of growth opportunities and rerun the regressions employed in Tables 6 to 9. The results show that the coefficients remain unchanged in sign and become even more statistically significant.

    7. Conclusion

    In the law and finance literature, ample studies use the index of investor legal protection developed by LLSV to explore the economic consequences of investor protection. We argue, however, that it may not make sense to take firm-level homogeneity and exogenousity for grunted. The level of legal protection for investors at the firm level may not only be heterogeneous but may also be endogenous even under identical legal environments. It is thus important to explore firm-level investor protection and its determinants.

    We have developed a theoretic model to illustrate how the controlling shareholder chooses the level of investor protection to pursue their own interests. Investor protection limits the controlling shareholder’s acquisition of private control benefit, and at the same time helps to improve that shareholder’s shared benefit. Controlling shareholders thus make decisions by trading offthe losses and gains resulted from improvements in investor protection. If the control structure of a company is complicated, the controlling shareholder can easily extract the private benefit of control. He is reluctant to enhance investor protection because his private benefit would be reduced greatly due to the required transparency. In contrast, if a company has good growth opportunities and is thus in need of external financing, investor protection would help the company to fund profitable opportunities with a lower cost of capital. Hence, the controlling shareholder would be willing to improve investor protection in that his shared benefit would increase with the increase in the entire equity.

    We use a measure of firm-level investor protection and examine the relationship between control structure, growth opportunities, and investor protection. Empirical evidence supports our theoretical prediction. Generally, the level of investor protection improves with a decrease in the opacity of the control structure and an increase in growth opportunities. Furthermore, better investment opportunities mitigate the negative correlation between investor protection and control structure opacity. Dividing the composite index of investor protection into three parts, we find that the coefficientsin the regression of the enforcement index are the most significant and those in the regression of the anti-director and disclosure indices unstable in their significance. It seems insufficient to simply set up mechanisms of investor protection in a relatively weak legal environment. Provided that the performance of an individual contract cannot be ensured, it is difficult for a company’s mechanisms to increase an insider’s cost of theft and lower the cost of capital. Thus, only the quality of the enforcement of investor protection is significant.

    Our empirical study is based on the open replies of Chinese listed companies to questions associated with investor protection asked by the CSRC. These unique data provide us with insight into firm-level investor protection within one country. However, the survey is not conducted regularly, which makes longitudinal research difficult. In addition, even though each listed company should be open in its replies to the survey because it bears the legal liability to tell the truth, the information is inevitably not flawless. Finally, although we use the lagged value of independent variables to explain the level of investor protection in 2007 to mitigate reverse causality, we have not thoroughly solved this problem. How to obtain better data and eliminate reverse causality are thus avenues for further research. It will also be necessary to do further work to grasp the intrinsic factors that affect corporate policy choices and find a way to compel listed companies to improve the quality of their investor protection, especially in transition economies.

    Bergman, N., Nicolaievslay, D., 2007. Investor protection and the coasian view. Journal of Financial Economics 84, 738-771.

    Claessens, S., Djankov, S., Lang, L., 2000. The separation of ownership and control in East Asian corporations. Journal of Finance Economics 58, 81-112.

    Coase, R., 1960. The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3, 1-44.

    Demirgü?-Kunt, A., Maksimovic, V., 1998. Law, finance, and firm growth. Journal of Finance 53, 2107-2139.

    Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Schleifer, A., 2008. The law and economics of self-dealing. Journal of Financial Economics 88, 430-465.

    Doidge, C., Karolyi, G., Stulz, R., 2004. Why are foreign firms listed in the U.S. worth more? Journal of Financial Economics 71, 205-238.

    Durnev, A., Kim, E. H., 2005. To steal or not to steal: firm attributes, legal environment, and valuation. Journal of Finance 60, 1461-1493.

    Dyck, A., Zingales, L., 2004. Private benefits of control: an international comparison. Journal of Finance 59, 537-600.

    Himmelberg C., Hubbard, R., Love, I., 2002. Investment, protection, ownership and the cost of capital. Policy Research Working Paper, World Bank.

    Holderness, C., 2003. A survey of blockholders and corporate control. Economic Policy Review 9, 51-63.

    Jiang, F., Zhi, X., Zhang, M., 2008. Investor protection and cost of equity: empirical study from China. Management World 2, 117-125. (In Chinese)

    Kallapur, S., Trombley, M., 1999. The association between investment opportunity set proxies and realisedgrowth. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 26, 505-519.

    La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., 1998. Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy 106, 1113-1155.

    La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., 1999. Corporate ownership around the world. Journal of Finance 54, 471-517.

    La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., 2000. Agency problems and dividend policies around the world. Journal of Finance 55, 1-33.

    La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., 2002. Investor protection and corporate valuation. Journal of Finance 57, 1147-1170.

    Luo, P., 2007. On the demarcation line between statutory and arbitrary regulations of Corporation Law: a legal principle analysis framework. China Legal Science 4, 69-84. (In Chinese)

    Shen, Y., Xiao, M., Lin, T., 2009. Investor protection and firm capital structure. Economic Research Journal, Forthcoming. (In Chinese)

    Shen, Y., Xu, N., Yang, Y., 2004. Empirical study on the historical practice of Chinese investor protection. Economics Research 9, 90-100. (In Chinese)

    * This study was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation (No. 70632001) and the Ministry of Education of the People’s Republic of China (No. 07JJD630009, No. 08JC630073). We would like to thank our research team for collecting the data. We are also grateful to Zhifeng Yang, Yuan Ding, Charles Chen, Xing Liu, and an anonymous referee for helpful comments. All remaining errors are our own.

    ** Corresponding author. E-mail address: xiaominmba@vip.sina.com. Correspondence address: School of Management, Xiamen University, Xiamen, China, 361005.

    猜你喜歡
    理工類專業(yè)英語英語教學(xué)
    基于“產(chǎn)出導(dǎo)向法”的軌道交通專業(yè)英語教學(xué)模式探索
    巧用“五法”激趣——以英語教學(xué)為例
    甘肅教育(2020年17期)2020-10-28 09:02:48
    如何提高英語教學(xué)的有效性
    甘肅教育(2020年6期)2020-09-11 07:45:28
    食品專業(yè)英語教學(xué)內(nèi)容和方法創(chuàng)新
    分部積分法在少數(shù)民族預(yù)科理工類高等數(shù)學(xué)教學(xué)中的探索
    Long的互動假說及其對英語教學(xué)的啟示
    長學(xué)制醫(yī)學(xué)生全程專業(yè)英語教學(xué)模式的構(gòu)建探討
    理工類院校韓國語專業(yè)轉(zhuǎn)型研究——以山東省為例
    大學(xué)理工類學(xué)生英語自主學(xué)習(xí)能力的調(diào)查
    高職高專公共英語教學(xué)中EGP+ESP模式的構(gòu)建
    久久久久久久精品精品| 成年人免费黄色播放视频| 亚洲成人av在线免费| 我的老师免费观看完整版| 大香蕉久久成人网| 搡女人真爽免费视频火全软件| 亚洲内射少妇av| 国产综合精华液| 色婷婷久久久亚洲欧美| 免费少妇av软件| 久久鲁丝午夜福利片| 久久热精品热| 十分钟在线观看高清视频www| 观看美女的网站| 国产精品嫩草影院av在线观看| 免费黄网站久久成人精品| 久久久久久久亚洲中文字幕| 国产精品一区二区在线观看99| 亚洲一区二区三区欧美精品| 亚洲精品国产色婷婷电影| 免费观看的影片在线观看| 国产一级毛片在线| 91精品一卡2卡3卡4卡| 两个人的视频大全免费| 国产精品免费大片| 亚洲精品日本国产第一区| 亚洲国产精品国产精品| 色94色欧美一区二区| 成人黄色视频免费在线看| 97在线视频观看| 亚洲综合精品二区| 久久久久久久亚洲中文字幕| 我的老师免费观看完整版| 国产伦精品一区二区三区视频9| 人人澡人人妻人| 久久人人爽人人片av| 在线观看人妻少妇| 精品国产露脸久久av麻豆| 国产一区二区在线观看日韩| 国产免费视频播放在线视频| 自线自在国产av| 国产一区二区三区综合在线观看 | 亚洲欧美成人综合另类久久久| 狂野欧美激情性xxxx在线观看| 日韩亚洲欧美综合| 国产淫语在线视频| 亚洲av中文av极速乱| 18禁裸乳无遮挡动漫免费视频| 美女福利国产在线| 十八禁高潮呻吟视频| 久久久久久久久久久免费av| 成人国产麻豆网| 男女高潮啪啪啪动态图| 熟女人妻精品中文字幕| 亚洲丝袜综合中文字幕| 一级,二级,三级黄色视频| 国产男人的电影天堂91| 黄色视频在线播放观看不卡| 日韩一区二区视频免费看| 国产精品久久久久久久电影| 亚洲精品乱久久久久久| 99久国产av精品国产电影| 高清毛片免费看| 一个人看视频在线观看www免费| 日韩人妻高清精品专区| 五月玫瑰六月丁香| 女性被躁到高潮视频| 国产色爽女视频免费观看| 国产成人精品在线电影| 国产成人91sexporn| 啦啦啦视频在线资源免费观看| 麻豆乱淫一区二区| av专区在线播放| 欧美xxⅹ黑人| 亚洲av福利一区| 国模一区二区三区四区视频| 国产高清三级在线| 制服丝袜香蕉在线| 大码成人一级视频| 国产精品久久久久久精品电影小说| 少妇精品久久久久久久| 亚洲欧美一区二区三区黑人 | 国产黄色免费在线视频| 精品午夜福利在线看| 老司机影院成人| 国产日韩欧美在线精品| 两个人的视频大全免费| 亚洲欧洲精品一区二区精品久久久 | 中文字幕av电影在线播放| 国产无遮挡羞羞视频在线观看| 国产毛片在线视频| 欧美bdsm另类| 性色avwww在线观看| 内地一区二区视频在线| 日韩熟女老妇一区二区性免费视频| 日韩中字成人| 午夜91福利影院| 丝瓜视频免费看黄片| 日韩熟女老妇一区二区性免费视频| 又大又黄又爽视频免费| 大香蕉97超碰在线| 久久婷婷青草| 蜜臀久久99精品久久宅男| 日韩av免费高清视频| 久久97久久精品| 欧美亚洲日本最大视频资源| 黄色一级大片看看| 精品一区二区免费观看| 亚洲综合精品二区| 日韩一区二区视频免费看| 你懂的网址亚洲精品在线观看| 美女国产视频在线观看| 成年人午夜在线观看视频| 免费少妇av软件| 国产免费福利视频在线观看| 国产亚洲欧美精品永久| 久久久久国产精品人妻一区二区| 亚洲精品一二三| 日韩av在线免费看完整版不卡| 欧美另类一区| a级毛色黄片| 国产成人一区二区在线| 久久精品国产自在天天线| 日日爽夜夜爽网站| 99热这里只有精品一区| 熟女电影av网| 亚洲欧洲日产国产| 另类精品久久| 女人久久www免费人成看片| 又大又黄又爽视频免费| 美女cb高潮喷水在线观看| 午夜福利视频在线观看免费| 美女大奶头黄色视频| 日本猛色少妇xxxxx猛交久久| 熟女人妻精品中文字幕| 伦精品一区二区三区| 一区二区三区精品91| 欧美少妇被猛烈插入视频| 热99国产精品久久久久久7| 大又大粗又爽又黄少妇毛片口| 国产成人精品无人区| 多毛熟女@视频| 欧美精品亚洲一区二区| 狠狠婷婷综合久久久久久88av| 黑人高潮一二区| 精品人妻熟女av久视频| 久久亚洲国产成人精品v| 亚洲精品亚洲一区二区| 久久国产亚洲av麻豆专区| 如何舔出高潮| 全区人妻精品视频| 久久影院123| 欧美亚洲日本最大视频资源| 国产熟女欧美一区二区| 亚洲国产精品一区三区| 日日啪夜夜爽| 大话2 男鬼变身卡| 免费久久久久久久精品成人欧美视频 | 18禁在线播放成人免费| 国产日韩欧美视频二区| 九草在线视频观看| 97超视频在线观看视频| 国产 精品1| 两个人免费观看高清视频| 国产精品国产三级专区第一集| 精品一区在线观看国产| a级毛色黄片| 人妻一区二区av| 亚洲一区二区三区欧美精品| 久久99热这里只频精品6学生| 欧美亚洲日本最大视频资源| 国产免费福利视频在线观看| 久久久久久久精品精品| 在线观看一区二区三区激情| 国产熟女午夜一区二区三区 | av网站免费在线观看视频| 搡老乐熟女国产| 久久久久久久大尺度免费视频| 免费av不卡在线播放| 最近最新中文字幕免费大全7| 久久久久网色| 午夜福利,免费看| 精品一区二区免费观看| 亚洲欧美一区二区三区国产| 久久久国产精品麻豆| 中文精品一卡2卡3卡4更新| 麻豆乱淫一区二区| 亚洲成人av在线免费| 国产男女内射视频| 亚洲人成网站在线播| 永久网站在线| 中文字幕av电影在线播放| 国产日韩欧美在线精品| 国产精品一国产av| 亚洲四区av| 日日摸夜夜添夜夜添av毛片| 国产精品国产三级国产av玫瑰| a级毛色黄片| 黑丝袜美女国产一区| 国产精品三级大全| 国产在线一区二区三区精| 天天操日日干夜夜撸| 校园人妻丝袜中文字幕| 日韩欧美一区视频在线观看| 人人妻人人澡人人看| 亚洲国产色片| 免费看光身美女| 精品午夜福利在线看| 亚洲精品456在线播放app| 欧美三级亚洲精品| 一二三四中文在线观看免费高清| 两个人免费观看高清视频| 观看av在线不卡| 中文字幕精品免费在线观看视频 | 久久99蜜桃精品久久| 性色avwww在线观看| a级片在线免费高清观看视频| 国产一区二区在线观看av| 少妇 在线观看| 岛国毛片在线播放| 中文字幕最新亚洲高清| 国产成人精品一,二区| 日本av免费视频播放| 热99国产精品久久久久久7| 免费看光身美女| 亚洲国产欧美在线一区| 丝瓜视频免费看黄片| 一级,二级,三级黄色视频| 大片免费播放器 马上看| 久久久欧美国产精品| 美女国产视频在线观看| 中文字幕亚洲精品专区| 在线观看免费日韩欧美大片 | 中文欧美无线码| 99久国产av精品国产电影| 亚洲精品美女久久av网站| 国产男人的电影天堂91| 18禁观看日本| 这个男人来自地球电影免费观看 | 国产精品国产三级专区第一集| 午夜福利影视在线免费观看| 久久精品国产亚洲av涩爱| 2018国产大陆天天弄谢| 亚洲国产精品国产精品| 久久精品国产自在天天线| 人妻少妇偷人精品九色| .国产精品久久| 亚洲国产精品一区三区| av视频免费观看在线观看| 美女国产视频在线观看| 狠狠精品人妻久久久久久综合| 成人毛片60女人毛片免费| 毛片一级片免费看久久久久| 在线精品无人区一区二区三| 男女高潮啪啪啪动态图| 一级毛片aaaaaa免费看小| 国产一区二区在线观看av| 国产亚洲一区二区精品| 久久免费观看电影| 亚洲国产精品成人久久小说| 老司机影院毛片| 18禁在线播放成人免费| 蜜桃在线观看..| 一本—道久久a久久精品蜜桃钙片| 超碰97精品在线观看| 久久久久久久久久久久大奶| 能在线免费看毛片的网站| 亚洲精品一二三| 亚洲av福利一区| 欧美成人午夜免费资源| 国产欧美日韩综合在线一区二区| 91精品国产九色| 中文天堂在线官网| 日韩欧美精品免费久久| 成人亚洲精品一区在线观看| 久久97久久精品| 91精品一卡2卡3卡4卡| 啦啦啦在线观看免费高清www| 亚洲人成网站在线播| 只有这里有精品99| 亚洲欧美中文字幕日韩二区| 男女免费视频国产| 美女cb高潮喷水在线观看| 国产精品.久久久| 免费大片18禁| 中国美白少妇内射xxxbb| 九色成人免费人妻av| 国产日韩欧美亚洲二区| 国产国语露脸激情在线看| 人妻系列 视频| 欧美精品一区二区大全| 在现免费观看毛片| 日本免费在线观看一区| 一区二区三区乱码不卡18| 伊人久久精品亚洲午夜| 观看美女的网站| 精品人妻在线不人妻| 亚州av有码| 九九爱精品视频在线观看| 免费人妻精品一区二区三区视频| 少妇人妻精品综合一区二区| 22中文网久久字幕| 人妻人人澡人人爽人人| 精品国产一区二区三区久久久樱花| av在线播放精品| 国产精品不卡视频一区二区| 久久ye,这里只有精品| 美女中出高潮动态图| 久久久久久久久大av| 欧美日韩亚洲高清精品| 婷婷色综合大香蕉| 在线观看www视频免费| 久久久亚洲精品成人影院| av不卡在线播放| 欧美日本中文国产一区发布| 亚洲av成人精品一二三区| 人人妻人人添人人爽欧美一区卜| 91久久精品国产一区二区三区| 国产精品一二三区在线看| 伦理电影大哥的女人| 十分钟在线观看高清视频www| 精品国产国语对白av| 国产成人av激情在线播放 | 色婷婷久久久亚洲欧美| 飞空精品影院首页| 色网站视频免费| www.色视频.com| 国模一区二区三区四区视频| 精品久久久噜噜| 婷婷色麻豆天堂久久| 激情五月婷婷亚洲| 亚洲国产精品国产精品| 成人黄色视频免费在线看| 男人爽女人下面视频在线观看| 日本黄色日本黄色录像| 色哟哟·www| 涩涩av久久男人的天堂| 国产黄频视频在线观看| 美女cb高潮喷水在线观看| www.av在线官网国产| 一级a做视频免费观看| 99久久人妻综合| 亚洲av中文av极速乱| 亚洲欧美清纯卡通| 伦精品一区二区三区| 精品久久国产蜜桃| 久久精品国产鲁丝片午夜精品| 国产精品 国内视频| 美女内射精品一级片tv| 国产成人午夜福利电影在线观看| 国产黄频视频在线观看| 亚洲欧美清纯卡通| 伦精品一区二区三区| 久久久久久伊人网av| 大香蕉97超碰在线| 99久久精品一区二区三区| 日本午夜av视频| 免费观看无遮挡的男女| av专区在线播放| 欧美日韩在线观看h| 亚洲成人手机| 亚洲人成网站在线播| 国产探花极品一区二区| 一级,二级,三级黄色视频| 美女xxoo啪啪120秒动态图| 如何舔出高潮| 欧美精品人与动牲交sv欧美| 久久精品久久精品一区二区三区| 久久久a久久爽久久v久久| 亚洲精品美女久久av网站| 三级国产精品欧美在线观看| 久久久久久久精品精品| 国产成人精品一,二区| 99热国产这里只有精品6| 亚洲精品第二区| 寂寞人妻少妇视频99o| 国产精品久久久久久av不卡| 久久狼人影院| 国产精品一国产av| 一级黄片播放器| 国产免费福利视频在线观看| 久久97久久精品| 日韩电影二区| 亚洲精品久久久久久婷婷小说| 午夜老司机福利剧场| 熟女av电影| 日韩制服骚丝袜av| 国产亚洲一区二区精品| 亚洲欧美一区二区三区黑人 | 国产精品99久久久久久久久| 丰满乱子伦码专区| 国产亚洲av片在线观看秒播厂| 欧美人与性动交α欧美精品济南到 | 欧美3d第一页| 亚洲成色77777| 亚洲情色 制服丝袜| 久久精品国产a三级三级三级| 国产精品偷伦视频观看了| 国产 精品1| 免费观看av网站的网址| 亚洲欧美日韩卡通动漫| 亚洲欧美色中文字幕在线| 日韩伦理黄色片| 美女福利国产在线| 久久97久久精品| 男女无遮挡免费网站观看| 日韩伦理黄色片| 成人二区视频| 国产极品天堂在线| 高清欧美精品videossex| 熟女av电影| 爱豆传媒免费全集在线观看| 久热久热在线精品观看| 亚洲精品乱码久久久久久按摩| 欧美 亚洲 国产 日韩一| 国产成人精品在线电影| 成人漫画全彩无遮挡| 老女人水多毛片| 久久99精品国语久久久| 亚洲欧美中文字幕日韩二区| 一级毛片黄色毛片免费观看视频| 搡老乐熟女国产| 午夜影院在线不卡| 亚洲色图 男人天堂 中文字幕 | 日韩av免费高清视频| 秋霞在线观看毛片| 久久国产精品大桥未久av| 少妇的逼好多水| 国产日韩欧美视频二区| 我要看黄色一级片免费的| 妹子高潮喷水视频| 亚洲av日韩在线播放| av电影中文网址| 女人久久www免费人成看片| 日韩av免费高清视频| 99久久人妻综合| av在线观看视频网站免费| 在现免费观看毛片| 欧美激情极品国产一区二区三区 | 亚洲av电影在线观看一区二区三区| 男人添女人高潮全过程视频| 大片电影免费在线观看免费| 日韩视频在线欧美| 亚洲国产欧美在线一区| 欧美97在线视频| 久久久久视频综合| 国产深夜福利视频在线观看| 看非洲黑人一级黄片| 建设人人有责人人尽责人人享有的| 我的老师免费观看完整版| av在线播放精品| 亚洲综合精品二区| 国产免费现黄频在线看| 91久久精品国产一区二区成人| 一级毛片aaaaaa免费看小| 超色免费av| 日韩av免费高清视频| 在线观看人妻少妇| 亚洲伊人久久精品综合| 欧美亚洲日本最大视频资源| 国产精品无大码| 日韩 亚洲 欧美在线| 91久久精品电影网| 亚洲综合精品二区| 久久久久久久久久人人人人人人| 欧美性感艳星| 亚洲第一av免费看| 亚洲国产精品专区欧美| 国产在视频线精品| 大片免费播放器 马上看| 精品亚洲成a人片在线观看| 欧美日韩精品成人综合77777| 丰满少妇做爰视频| 亚洲av二区三区四区| 精品国产国语对白av| 精品酒店卫生间| 亚洲欧美日韩卡通动漫| 十八禁网站网址无遮挡| 国产综合精华液| 日本黄色日本黄色录像| 一区二区三区四区激情视频| 伦理电影大哥的女人| 热re99久久国产66热| 久久久国产精品麻豆| 午夜福利视频精品| 黄色配什么色好看| 中国国产av一级| 久久这里有精品视频免费| 桃花免费在线播放| 黑人巨大精品欧美一区二区蜜桃 | 欧美亚洲 丝袜 人妻 在线| 久久久久国产精品人妻一区二区| 五月开心婷婷网| 午夜福利在线观看免费完整高清在| www.色视频.com| 亚洲五月色婷婷综合| 黑丝袜美女国产一区| 亚洲高清免费不卡视频| 亚洲成色77777| 久久久久人妻精品一区果冻| 午夜影院在线不卡| 高清av免费在线| 亚洲精品一二三| av在线播放精品| 国产精品一区二区在线观看99| 精品国产国语对白av| 欧美最新免费一区二区三区| 一本久久精品| 成人亚洲精品一区在线观看| 国产av国产精品国产| www.av在线官网国产| 日日爽夜夜爽网站| 亚洲经典国产精华液单| 高清黄色对白视频在线免费看| 国产av国产精品国产| 免费高清在线观看日韩| 2021少妇久久久久久久久久久| 伊人亚洲综合成人网| a级毛色黄片| 少妇被粗大猛烈的视频| 伊人久久国产一区二区| 一区二区av电影网| 中文字幕制服av| 国产欧美日韩综合在线一区二区| 亚洲av不卡在线观看| 久久精品久久久久久噜噜老黄| 99久久人妻综合| 国产男人的电影天堂91| 亚洲人成网站在线观看播放| 校园人妻丝袜中文字幕| .国产精品久久| 国产精品熟女久久久久浪| 欧美精品一区二区大全| 亚洲国产最新在线播放| 制服丝袜香蕉在线| 熟女人妻精品中文字幕| 18在线观看网站| 狂野欧美白嫩少妇大欣赏| 午夜日本视频在线| 国产视频内射| 久久精品久久久久久久性| 免费高清在线观看日韩| 99九九在线精品视频| 99精国产麻豆久久婷婷| 能在线免费看毛片的网站| 肉色欧美久久久久久久蜜桃| 能在线免费看毛片的网站| 精品国产一区二区三区久久久樱花| av在线播放精品| 少妇高潮的动态图| 亚洲成人手机| 久久人妻熟女aⅴ| 一本一本综合久久| 日韩一本色道免费dvd| 日韩 亚洲 欧美在线| 18在线观看网站| 精品99又大又爽又粗少妇毛片| 久久久久久伊人网av| 亚洲丝袜综合中文字幕| 亚洲情色 制服丝袜| 亚洲经典国产精华液单| 国产亚洲精品久久久com| freevideosex欧美| 久久久久久久国产电影| 日韩大片免费观看网站| 国产欧美日韩一区二区三区在线 | 最近的中文字幕免费完整| 国产精品国产三级专区第一集| 中文字幕亚洲精品专区| 日韩三级伦理在线观看| 亚洲精品一二三| 好男人视频免费观看在线| 国产女主播在线喷水免费视频网站| 一级黄片播放器| 男人操女人黄网站| 欧美日韩亚洲高清精品| 视频区图区小说| 国产日韩欧美亚洲二区| 亚洲av福利一区| 中国美白少妇内射xxxbb| 免费观看性生交大片5| 大陆偷拍与自拍| 国产黄色视频一区二区在线观看| 亚洲欧美一区二区三区黑人 | 99久久精品国产国产毛片| 免费观看av网站的网址| 中文乱码字字幕精品一区二区三区| 欧美精品一区二区大全| 国产 精品1| 欧美精品一区二区免费开放| av黄色大香蕉| 成人影院久久| 人人妻人人澡人人爽人人夜夜| 久久久久精品性色| 观看av在线不卡| 亚洲国产毛片av蜜桃av| 欧美少妇被猛烈插入视频| 国产一区二区三区综合在线观看 | 中文乱码字字幕精品一区二区三区| 久久久亚洲精品成人影院| 国产亚洲一区二区精品| 看非洲黑人一级黄片| 精品久久久噜噜| 久久99热这里只频精品6学生| 亚洲欧美一区二区三区黑人 | 欧美精品国产亚洲| 99国产精品免费福利视频| 91精品国产国语对白视频| 纵有疾风起免费观看全集完整版| 91精品国产九色| 777米奇影视久久| 一个人看视频在线观看www免费| 中文字幕精品免费在线观看视频 | 久久久久久久久大av| 午夜视频国产福利|