• <tr id="yyy80"></tr>
  • <sup id="yyy80"></sup>
  • <tfoot id="yyy80"><noscript id="yyy80"></noscript></tfoot>
  • 99热精品在线国产_美女午夜性视频免费_国产精品国产高清国产av_av欧美777_自拍偷自拍亚洲精品老妇_亚洲熟女精品中文字幕_www日本黄色视频网_国产精品野战在线观看 ?

    Government Regulation, Enforcement, and Economic Consequences in a Transition Economy: Empirical Evidence from Chinese Listed Companies Implementing the Split Share Structure Reform*

    2009-04-05 17:30:56DequnJingShngkunLingndDonghuChen
    China Journal of Accounting Research 2009年1期

    Dequn Jing, Shngkun Lingnd Donghu Chen,**

    aResearch Institute of Accounting and Finance, Nanjing University, China

    Government Regulation, Enforcement, and Economic Consequences in a Transition Economy: Empirical Evidence from Chinese Listed Companies Implementing the Split Share Structure Reform*

    Dequan Jianga, Shangkun Liangaand Donghua Chena,**

    aResearch Institute of Accounting and Finance, Nanjing University, China

    In a changing transition economy, Chinese government regulations that adopt the relatively simple bright line rule formula are enforceable in practice. Taking the early reform-oriented policies of the China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) as an example, we find that the CSRC did not consider local enthusiasm for reform when allocating IPO resources because of the high enforcement costs involved. We also find that CSRC listed company regulations were enforced due to the lower costs involved in verifying regulatory violations, and that listed companies that completed the reform process were given priority in public refinancing. We present empirical evidence supporting the theoretical basis for the hypotheses outlined above. We also conclude that companies that completed the reform process in 2005 were of significantly higher quality and that the SEO regulation did not affect stock market efficiency. These findings enhance our understanding of the efficiency of government regulation in a transition economy.JEL classification: G32; G38; G15

    Government regulation; Enforcement; Economic consequences; Split Share Structure Reform (SSSR)

    1. Introduction

    In a modern market economy, government influence extends to almost all areas of social life. Government can not only influence a market economy through financial, monetary, and other forms of macro-policies, but also lay down the rules of the game in the field of micro-enterprise development by such means as economic regulations. In economics, the state intervention principle of the “market defect theory” posits that government intervention has certain inevitability about it. A well-functioning market mechanism can put social resources to the most effective use. However, there is a need to give the market mechanism itself room to function in an orderly, competitive environment to ensure the economic efficiency of the system in which it operates. If the market mechanism has an inherent weakness that prevents it from establishing or maintaining the systemic environment in which it operates at a low cost, this indicates the presence of a market defect. If the market is operated according to laissez-faire principles, it will lead to unfairness or inefficiency. The government public welfare person hypothesis postulates that government represents the public interest and that government regulations are made in response to a public need. The genesis of regulations lies not only in imperfect competition, the non-equilibrium status of market operations and market deficiency, but also includes the need to prevent and correct undesirable market outcomes. Glaeser and Shleifer (2003) found that in the second half of the 19th century, when the American society was in a tumultuous state, because the impartiality of the legal system could not be guaranteed, government regulation had to deal with the challenges of an ever-changing economic environment to have any real effect. It can be argued that regulation is more efficient than the judiciary system in that regulators have a stronger incentive than judges to identify and deal with violations.1Taking into account the economic development seen in China’s transition to date, it may be necessary to strengthen government regulation from a structural perspective, but the loopholes and flipside of government regulation must be settled promptly (Sun, 2004). China, in its period of economic transition, must go through the process of “market failure - government regulation”, and it is only after doing so that can establish a modern form of government regulation. Those who put forward ideas on future public policy for China should pay attention to the establishment of the government regulatory system, which is one of the public management system “modules,” thus strengthening the government’s control functions (Wang, 2004).

    In a complex and changing environment, government performance is determined by politics, the economy, culture, and a number of other factors (La Porta et al., 1998).The question then becomes whether government regulation can be effectively enforced.Glaeser and Shleifer (2001) formulated a relatively simple “clear rule” (the “bright line rule”) that makes it possible to reduce implementation costs in the public and private spheres and that it is conducive to supervision by the regulatory agencies that set the rules. The “clear rules” used in many domains, such as in the legal system and in determining the legality of the actions of economic entities, are elaborate when viewed from the perspective of this rule (Glaeser and Shleifer, 2000). When the regulatory object is complex and “the clear rule” has not been followed, whether there are cost/ benefit restraints, whether the regulators will enforce the regulation, or will do so at a discount, and whether the original intent of the regulator can be realized are all questions worthy of thorough investigation.

    CSRC regulation over the course of the listed company SSSR process in China provides an excellent opportunity to test this theory2The split share structure refers to the existence of both tradable shares on the stock exchange and a large volume of non-tradable shares owned by the state and legally defined entities in the Chinese capital market.This was a peculiar solution developed in the course of transforming China’s economic structure, and has led to flaws in the capital market in terms of a distorted pricing mechanism, resource allocation inefficiency, and the invalidation of market price as an innate factor promoting efficiency. The split share structure has limited the power of substantial shareholders who lack common interests as the basis for corporate governance. On the whole, the split share structure has been a major counterforce against the opening up and long-term development of the capital market.. The listed company SSSR process is a key step in the return to a stock market-based system and the optimization and advancement of a system originally intended to run along market lines; it is the result of the game equilibrium between the holders of tradable shares and non-tradable shares on issues such as separation reform plans and the correct market pricing. However, if the market is allowed to take the lead in setting its own parameters, the process is bound to be slow, which will affect the pace of capital market reform and development. Because there is unlikely to be special legislation passed for the SSSR, the CSRC will elect to use its regulatory and supervisory powers to incentivize listed companies to complete the reform at an early date. Senior CSRC officials have indicated on many occasions in public that policy support will be given to ensure an active share reform process; that CSRC attention will be focused on key areas and key enterprises to promote work undertaken to further the reform process; that regions should promote the SSSR process actively and implement preferential policies at the right time; and that for companies which have already completed the reform process different policies should be adopted to encourage them to use the capital market as a way of strengthening their operations.3The press conference on “China’s reform and development of capital markets,” which was held by the Information Office of the State Council on 29 June 2005; The CSRC analyzed “two laws” at a video conference held on 31 December 2005 and a CSRC press conference about “the issuance of securities in listed company management (draft)” held on 16 April 2006.

    After distinguishing between the different levels of commitment made by the CSRC to individual regions and listed companies, we find it is harder to commit on a local basis. Not only is the cost of information processing for local regulations higher, but there is a lack of clear regulatory rules. Under such conditions, regardless of whether theCSRC maintains its commitment to regional reform, regions that implement the SSSR with more enthusiasm will get a greater share of IPO (initial public offering) resources. On the other hand, because the power of the CSRC to regulate listed companies is explicit, companies that complete the reform process at an early stage will be given priority to use SEOs (seasoned equity offerings). Implementing regulatory policy involves relatively low costs and is easy to fulfill. While previous studies have shown that regulation can easily lead to opportunistic behavior (Stigler and Friedland, 1962; Stigler, 1971; Chung, 2002; Chen, Ye and Chen, 2003), there are certain features of the SSSR, such as its short timeframe and high level of intensity, as well as the features of the corresponding regulatory policy such as its transience and high profile, that suggest the SSSR will not lead to opportunistic behavior among listed companies. These issues constitute the basis of our paper.

    The rest of this paper is structured as follows. Section 2 examines the institutional background and extant literature, outlines the theoretical analysis, and sets out our research hypotheses. Section 3 describes our sample, variables, and descriptive statistics, and Section 4 establishes an empirical model used for empirical stability testing. We present our conclusions and the limitations of this study in Section 5.

    2. Background, Literature Review, and Theoretical Analysis

    The pattern of Chinese economic reform conforms to a government-directed model. This model has both advantages and disadvantages. On the one hand, because the Chinese government is superior to other social organizations due to its greater level of authority, it will take a relatively shorter period of time to move from the old system to a new one (Zhu et al., 2005). However, in a country with a complex economic, cultural, and political background, the gap between expectation and reality is sometimes large. This phenomenon is often referred to as “the behavioral deviation” (Zhu et al., 2005)4According to the reasoning given, behavioral deviations can be divided into two types: transitional behavioral deviations and flawed behavioral deviations. The former type is caused by transitional policy. For example, in the initial period of economic reform, some managers used their powers to carry on arbitrage. Another example is the single big holder phenomenon arising due to the prohibition on trading state-owned shares and legal shares. Flawed behavioral deviations are caused by policy flaws or the lag in spiritual development in society, as seen in violations, broken promises, fraud, etc.. The government often uses regulation to deal with this problem. Shleifer (2005) propose the enforcement theory, in which government regulation is simply the balance of the cost of government dictatorship and the cost of social dictatorship. Government regulation is vastly superior in controlling disorder. Regulators are more active in discovering violations, and are more difficult to bribe than judges. Pistor and Xu (2002) consider that regulators can be appointed from a pool of experts. Such regulators may be driven to achieve social objectives in certain domains and to regulate the stock market tocontribute to the realization of such goals. Glaeser and Shleifer (2001) pointed out that government quotas are more effective than tax controls in realizing policy objectives. Although quotas limit certain aspects of behavior, the low investigation costs involved can increase the effectiveness of policy and raise the efficiency of society as a whole.

    In China, regulation also has advantages and disadvantages, and regulation brings certain costs. Regulatory agencies, in an effort to exchange their powers for economic benefits, prefer to expend their powers on economic affairs, increase the volume of administrative examination projects (Li, 2005). Government regulation is a common route to reform in China. In spite of some negative effects, government regulation also has positive effects (Wang, 20045Taking the US as an example, in the 1990s, remarkable progress was made in government regulations on science, technology, and environmental protection. On average, income resulting from government regulations on environmental protection was between $16,500-1,358,000 million, and income derived from highway regulations was between $25,400-45,700 million. The income derived from these two areas outweighed the costs involved.; Chen et al., 2008). Few changes have been seen in the government regulatory system since the Chinese economic reforms were initiated in the late 1970s. Chinese government regulatory organizations have consistently had a set of both control powers and management powers, giving rise to the epithet “comprehensive regulatory agency.” As one of the direct government agencies, the CRSC is not different in this respect (Mao, 2007). Due to its concerns over the potential stock market disorder, the CSRC has used quantitative controls to regulate the IPO market. From 1989 to 1998, the regulatory pattern was consistently one of “institutional approval”6Under the institutional approval model, if a company wished to apply for an IPO, it first had to seek permission from the regional government or management department of the company concerned, according to its administrative relationship. The company could then submit the application to the local securities control section. If the application was passed at this stage, it was submitted to the CSRC with a specific IPO amount indicated and the documents were officially prepared. In the last step, the CSRC issued its final examination opinion. If no problems were identified in the opinion, the IPO application was successful.(Chen et al., 2008). However, the detailed ways in which this system has been applied have differed: in 1993-1995, the method applied was one of “overall quota controls, division of IPO opportunities”; in 1996-1998, a “total quota controls, limit on IPO applications” method was applied (Li, 2001). After 1998, the CSRC introduced an“examination committee,” marking a transition from the “institutional approval” system to one of “institutional registration.”7Under the institutional registration model, companies satisfying the standards specified in the Company Law and Securities Law can make IPO applications and do not require government approval. The CSRC decides whether the application is accepted according to applicable provisions.The CSRC no longer used a quantitative target in principle, but any unused quota could be used in following years. Although the CSRC officially introduced an “approval system” in March 2001, it was not implemented in an efficient manner. The CSRC has maintained consistent control over which companies are permitted to launch IPOs (Chen et al., 2008).

    The power of the CSRC to determine which companies can launch IPOs or SEOs may have had a great influence on the SSSR. Every year, when determining the amountof stock to be issued in the coming year, the CSRC, either openly or privately, is obliged to consider the issue of assigning IPO and SEO licenses to firms based in different locations. To the CSRC, exercising this power involves balancing local development concerns and following micro-level government policy. To regional governments, being awarded an IPO or SEO represents a major financing opportunity that can be used to assist local development. Local governments have an incentive to promote the SSSR process. As a result, to promote the SSSR, the CSRC must and may utilize its control right nimbly, shift its pressure, and defend its prestige (Chen et al., 2008). In this way, the CSRC connects local government enthusiasm for the SSSR with the IPO and SEO resource allocation process. If listed companies drag their feet in implementing the SSSR, the CSRC is likely to reduce the number of IPO and SEO opportunities available in the region, and instead give opportunities to regions in which the SSSR is actively implemented. Government regulation comes in several main forms. It includes not only stable long-term policies, but also changeable temporary policies; it is not limited to prohibitive control, but also includes offering incentives (such as benefit pledges); and is not limited to support control, but also encompasses substitution control. In this paper, we view CSRC regulation as a temporary, changeable, incentivized, and substitutable form of control behavior.

    The theoretical analysis presented above is consistent with CSRC policy. “Opinions of the CSRC, the National Capital Committee, the Ministry of Finance, the People’s Bank, and the Department of Commercial Affairs about the SSSR” were issued on August 23, 2005. This document pointed out that all parts of the State Council Department should strengthen their cooperation with each other to give impetus to the SSSR and maintain the smooth development of the stock market. It also noted that local governments should make great use of their comprehensive resources and strengthen their leadership to promote the SSSR. Companies that have completed the SSSR process are first in line for an SEO. On April 16, 2006, a CSRC public relations spokesperson released policy guidance called “early reform, early profit” at a press conference on “IPO management method (basic plan).” The same spokesperson said that to alleviate the pressure resulting from concentrating financing activity on the stock market, companies would be unable to launch SEOs until six months after completing the SSSR process. In addition, IPOs would first be resumed in regions in which the market value of companies that had completed the SSSR process reached a certain proportion. Although there were certain differences between the CSRC’s pledge and the traditional regulatory approach, the new requirements announced had a tangible influence on regions and companies alike. Regions and companies that displayed differing levels of enthusiasm were to be treated differently: regions in which SSSR tasks were completed quickly would be granted more IPO resources, and companies that completed the SSSR process at an early date would have a greater chance of securing SEOs. This type of control limits IPO and SEO activities, and at the same time oversees regions and companies in their SSSR activities and spurs them to speed up the SSSR process. In this sense, this form of regulatory control is no different to traditional regulation. What’s more, this control can be seen asa form of “substitution control”8In practice, the CSRC has two different functions. First, the CSRC oversees the stock market. It must supervise the market to prevent the occurrence of illegal activities. This type of control can be seen as a form of “support control.” Second, the CSRC is responsible for examining IPOs and SEOs. This type of control has been called“vicarious control” (Chen et al., 2003).. It involves a substitution of, rather than support for, the market. The ultimate aim of the SSSR is to deliver an effective market mechanism that allows for long-term, smooth development of the stock market. However, if no active steps are taken and the market is left to develop of its own accord, it is likely to take a long time to develop. To quickly resolve the difficult issues which have been part of the Chinese stock market for several years, the CSRC has eventually used a nonmarket based method to “l(fā)ure” companies.

    In the SSSR context, the CSRC offers two forms of incentive: IPO incentives and SEO incentives, both of which are valuable to regional governments and companies. Companies given an IPO or SEO opportunity will receive a great deal of money to assist corporate development. If a company develops its business, it is likely to create more job opportunities in the area and will pay more tax to the regional government. For these reasons, IPO and SEO incentives are highly treasured by local governments and companies, making it necessary to prioritize active promotion of the SSSR. On the other hand, these two incentives are not the same, and each has its own distinctive characteristics. First, for IPO incentives, the applicable provisions are not explicit. Two reform attempts were made before the current SSSR, indicating that the market discovery function of the CSRC was inadequate9The CSRC made two attempts to resolve the non-tradable share problem in 1999 and 2001, by rationing and selling state shares. However, neither of these two attempts was particularly successful. This problem has increasingly stymied the development of the stock market..If there is a lack of simple, clear, and effective rules, and exclusive reliance on the rule that “the market value of companies [that have completed the SSSR process] has reached a certain proportion”10This standard is fuzzy and inaccurate, especially when one considers several companies with a huge market value. For example, CPCC (China Petroleum Chemical Corporation) accounts for 11.29% of the total market capitalization of listed companies. For this reason, it is clearly inappropriate to assess the SSSR speed of Beijing based on this standard alone. The CSRC may take into account the percentage of companies that have completed the SSSR process as a supplementary standard., it is difficult for the CSRC to accurately assess the efforts made by a local government in implementing the SSSR11Hay et al. (1996) considered the simplification violation discovery procedure and suggested that Russia use “the clear rule” in its legal reforms.. On the other hand, it is also difficult to determine the yardsticks on which the CSRC is inclined to focus. Should it use the number of IPOs in a region, the amount of capital raised in IPOs, the IPO growth rate in comparison with the historical rate or with other areas, and solely IPO or SEO criteria, or both? This lack of clarity in regional regulation may affect the utilization of the SSSR and the realization of its goals. Second, the authentication and examination procedure for IPO authorization is complex and can be influenced by various factors. As a result of the differences in economic development across regions and differences in growth ratesacross product and essential factor (such as financial factor) markets, companies allowed to have IPO may not be concentrate in regions that actively promote the SSSR process. High information processing costs are likely to prevent the CSRC from regulating the market effectively. For these reasons, in determining which companies can have an IPO and which companies are allowed to have IPOs first, it is difficult for the CSRC to rely predominantly on the proportion rule12Take Beijing as an example. On May 24, 2006, the number of companies that had completed the SSSR process was 68, representing 80.95% of all Beijing listed companies. This percentage was the 7th highest among all provinces (cities). However, if ranked according to the percentage of market value represented by companies that had completed the SSSR process, Beijing came in last. By market value, only 38.06% of its companies had completed the SSSR process.. If the CRSC relaxes its IPO standards excessively to speed up the SSSR process, the costs resulting from low-quality IPOs may be large. Third, the IPO incentive is indirect. Through the IPO incentive, the CSRC first incentivizes local governments, which then encourage local companies to reform. An increase in the number of links in the system may result in lower efficiency and higher costs. If more companies are controlled by the central government rather than the local government, the situation may worsen and difficulties presented by regional incentives will increase. In comparison, the rules on SEO incentives are explicit. SEO incentives are targeted at listed companies. These companies are generally of higher quality, so the SEO examination procedure is simpler and faster. SEO incentives are more direct. It is easier for the CSRC both to appreciate the efforts made by companies in the SSSR process and to meet its commitment. The CSRC can give more active companies a greater likelihood of SEOs. In short, while IPO incentives are “point-to-face” incentives, SEO incentives are “point-to-point” incentives. To compare the two, “point-to-face” incentives are fuzzier, whereas “point-to-point” incentives are clearer. More difficulties and costs are involved in “point-to-face” incentives, whereas “point-to-point” incentives can help reduce policy carrying costs. With “point-to-face” incentives, because it is difficult for the CSRC to observe the efforts of local governments, it is difficult to reward them. In contrast, with “point-to-point” incentives, because it is easy for the CSRC to observe the efforts of companies, it is easy to reward them. Therefore, to achieve the objective of completing the SSSR process as quickly as possible, the probability of the CSRC realizing its SOE incentive pledge is greater.

    Because the CSRC is a government department, the SSSR is founded on the government's credit. To maintain this credit, CSRC has introduced several measures designed to prevent potential opportunistic behavior among listed companies. The requirement that SSSR companies pay satisfactory compensation for tradable shares is one of these measures13The compensation paid to tradable shareholders represents a large amount of money to the company. Generally speaking, high quality companies are in a position to pay a satisfactory amount of compensation at an earlier stage.. Under this measure, low-quality companies which speed up the SSSR process to increase their chances of being given IPO opportunities will be restrained.

    Based on the above theoretical analysis, and considering both IPO and SEO restarts14If the majority of companies complete the SSSR process, a time limit will be set. All IPO shares become tradable after this point in time., we predict that:

    Hypothesis 1:It is difficult for the CSRC to carry out regional reform effectively because of the high information processing and policy carrying costs involved.

    Regions active in the SSSR process may not receive extra IPO support from the CSRC. When the CSRC allocates IPOs, several important factors are likely to be taken into account. The first of these factors is the extent to which the region is economically developed and the degree of growth in the capital market. In areas that have experienced rapid economic development and a good degree of growth in the capital market, the quality of companies applying for IPOs may be better, and the number of companies meeting the requirements may be larger. The second factor is the number of listed companies in a region. To balance the pace of development across regions and promote undeveloped areas, the CSRC may give more IPO opportunities to these areas. The third factor influencing IPO allocation decisions may be where decision-making power resides. The CSRC may have less influence in areas that have a high level of political clout. These areas find it easy to obtain IPO allocations, even if they have not been active in promoting the SSSR.

    Further, we predict that:

    Hypothesis 2:It is relatively straightforward for the CSRC to control the SEO process.

    Companies that actively implement the SSSR are likely to have a greater chance of an SEO. When the CSRC allocates SEOs, several other factors may be important. The first such factor is the level of compensation paid15Wu et al. (2008) found that the relation between institutional investor shareholdings and the compensation rate was negative. This suggests that institutional investors did not play a significant role in protecting small shareholders. Jin et al. (2005) and Chen et al. (2008) found that there were institutional investor and major shareholder conspiracies in the SSSR. As a result, the greater the number of shares held by institutional investors, the lower compensation rate would be.. Good protection for tradable investors is an important safeguard of a smooth SSSR process. The current SSSR has an impact on the long-term development of China’s stock market and is observed from the top level down. The current SSSR also represents an important political task to the CSRC. For this reason, while completing the share reform promptly, the CSRC must ensure the SSSR is carried out smoothly. All else being equal, the higher the compensation ratio paid by a company, the better the level of protection afforded to tradable investors. This last result is consistent with the CSRC’s goal. This suggests that companies that pay a higher compensation ratio are more likely to be offered an SEO by the CSRC. Thesecond factor is company ownership. SOEs (state-owned enterprises) are owned by the government, one arm of which is the CSRC. As a result, SOEs may have a better chance of securing an SEO.

    Our final prediction is as follows:

    Hypothesis 3:CSRC regulations on the SEO process may not reduce the efficiency of the stock market.

    The timeframe for the current SSSR is short and the level of intensity is high. In this brief, centralized policy change, it may be difficult for companies to take opportunistic countermeasures immediately. At the same time, the CSRC mechanism (the satisfactory compensation ratio policy) offers an additional guarantee of SEO company quality.

    3. Sample and Data Description

    3.1. Sample

    The data come mainly from the CCER economic and financial research database of Peking University, with the remaining data collected manually. Following the official launch of the listed company share reform, IPOs and refinancing were suspended until June 19, 200616China CAMC Engineering (002051) was first listed on June 19, 2006 after re-opening of IPO. Beijing Hualian Hypermarket (600361) was first refinanced on May 18, 2006 after re-opening of SEO.. Our sample period runs from April 29, 2005 to June 18, 2006. A total of 985 observations for companies that have completed the share reform process are available.

    We examine regional performance during the share reform process and the subsequent IPO resource gains made (over the period June 19, 2006 to December 31, 2007) to verify whether the CSRC honored its commitment. We also observe the distribution of companies for which the CSRC had rejected listing applications.

    3.2. Data Description

    The information shown in Table 1 includes the distribution of companies that have completed the share reform process (Share Reform), IPO resources (IPO), and companies that have had listing applications rejected (IPO-REJECT)17Both IPO and IPO-REJECT include the review link for IPO applicants..

    Table 1 shows that a number of companies in economically developed areas such as Beijing, Shanghai, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, and Guangdong have completed the share reform process. On the one hand, these areas have more listed companies than others. On the other hand, the pace of economic development in these regions may have affected local enthusiasm and resulted in these companies being better prepared when required to implement the share reform. In addition, as cities that host stock exchanges, Shanghai and Guangdong may have been more enthusiastic about the share reform than other regions. We also find that these areas were allocated greater IPO resources.

    From the time distribution perspective, we find that a greater number of listed companies implemented the share reform in 2006 than in the previous year. The CSRC regarded the share reform as its primary task in developing the capital market and strove to ensure that the reform was basically completed by the end of 2006. The number of companies that launched IPOs increased substantially in 2007. At the same time, more company applications were rejected because the CSRC did not relax the IPO eligibility criteria.

    Table 2 shows that an average of about 32 companies around the country completed the reform each year and that there were significant regional differences. Fewer listed companies came from the central and western regions due to the relatively low level of economic development in these areas. In addition, because the CSRC prioritized the 11 key provinces (municipalities) in the course of the reform process, regional differences were unavoidable18On June 8, 2006, Shang Fulin, the CSRC Chairman, said that Chinese listed companies should strive to complete the reform before the end of the year and that the CSRC was bound to focus on the 11 key provinces (municipalities) to play a positive role in promoting economic growth in those areas.. Each region had an average of 6 IPO companies. Due to the many factors involved, the geographical distribution of IPO resources was very uneven, ranging from 0 to 35 IPOs per region. Table 2 also shows that a maximum number of 10 applications were rejected in any one region.

    Figure 1 presents the number of companies in each region which implemented the reform and the IPO resources gained; on the whole, the trend is irrelevant. Although developed areas such as Guangdong and Jiangsu had greater access to IPO resources, their IPO growth was smaller. This indicates that the CSRC’s IPO policy did not favor reform-active areas, which actually experienced a substantial reduction in IPOs in comparison with the previous period. Figure 2 reports the regional distribution of IPO rejections. The rejection rate for applications made from reform-active areas did not fall, and there was no trend in the opposite direction.

    Table 3 shows that 985 listed companies had completed the share reform and 190 companies had been authorized to conduct an SEO by December 31, 2007. A higher proportion of companies (30%) that completed the reform process in 2005 obtained an SEO quota. In contrast, only 11% of the companies that completed the reform process in 2006 were authorized to launch SEOs. Re-opened refinancing gave the capital market an opportunity to release the pressure that had built up, with companies that implemented the share reform earlier being given priority.

    The odds of being granted IPO or SEO resources are affected by many complicated factors. Taking all these factors into account would result in an extremely complex model. We therefore select a number of suitable variables that have crucial impacts on the issues we investigate. Table 4 gives the definitions for the main variables used in this paper.

    Regional-enthusiasm is used as a direct measure of whether a region was motivated to complete the reform process at an early stage. After two successful pilot programs, all listed companies were required to start the reform process on September 9, 200519On September 9, 2005, the State-owned Assets Supervision and Administration Commission of the State Council issued “Notices about Managing the State-owned Shares of Listed Companies in the Share Reform,”which prompted Chinese listed companies to begin their preparations for the share reform. The CSRC then took measures designed to push forward the reform in an active, steady, and orderly manner.. We measure regional enthusiasm by the proportion of total market value represented by companies that completed the reform process, with a higher proportion indicating a higher degree of enthusiasm. The operating efficiency of the government and the financial market and the level of competition were relatively high in such areas, and the rule of law was relatively strong. The CSRC gave priority to listed companies in these areas because of their contributions to a normally functioning capital market and the development and improvement of the market. This is also in keeping with the original intention of the CSRC. “Shell resource” is the definition used for listed companies. A shell resource should be homogeneous and the value of the shell should remain the same20A “shell resource” refers to the qualification of a listed company to be traded publicly. The value of a shell resource is reflected in the secondary market. Shell resources result from market regulations and are characterized by the IPO quota system. A shell resource is formed by the use of an IPO quota and successful listing. A shell resource has an actual market price after listing because it is tradable (Yang, 2003).. To achieve balanced development across regions, the CSRC tends to give certain quotas to areas in which only a few listed companies are based. Districts with higher political status may get more IPO resources. When we test Hypothesis 1, regionalenthusiasm serves as the most important explanatory variable.

    We note that the higher the level of enthusiasm for implementing the reform, the earlier the reform process was completed, and the smaller the batch offirms involved.The batches offirms that participated in the two pilot programs are defined as -2 and -1, respectively. After the start of the overall reform process, the first batch of companies to have completed the reform is defined as 1, etc. Due to the existence of two pilot groups, we adjust the batches when calculating listed company enthusiasm: firmenthusiasm equals batch originally involved plus three. In the course of the share reform, institutional investors and non-tradable shares may have “conspired” against small and medium-sized shareholders. High compensation rates directly reflect companies’ efforts to protect small and medium-sized investors. One of the reform principles applied by the CSRC is to protect the rights and interests of small and medium-sized investors, indicating that the compensation rates paid may have affected the CSRC’s SEO resource allocation decisions. Applications made by state-owned companies may also have been accepted earlier. Profitability is a prerequisite to an SEO: the more profitable the company, the greater the chance of obtaining a quota. In examining the CSRC’s SEO policy, we regard firm-enthusiasm as the most important explanatory variable.

    Table 5 lists the descriptive statistics for the other regression variables.

    4. Empirical Results

    4.1. Test of CSRC’s IPO Policy

    We use multivariate analysis to test whether a region’s higher level of enthusiasm for the reform process resulted in its gaining a bigger IPO quota. The OLS regression model to be estimated (Model 1) is specified as follows:

    Table 6 shows that only the market index (MARKET) and the degree of shell resource scarcity (SCARE) variables had a significant influence, and that the regression results are not affected.

    Table 7 shows that the distribution of IPO quotas was not significantly affected by regional enthusiasm. Supervising the various regions was complex and it was costly to control the implementation process. Because the CSRC found it difficult to accurately assess the reform efforts made in the various regions, it found it difficult to deliver more IPO quotas to active areas. Regions with higher political status did not receive a higher quota, indicating that the influence of the CSRC in these regions had not diminished. To achieve balanced economic development across regions, the CSRC is inclined to allocate a reasonable quota to regions experiencing a scarcity of shell resources. At the same time, the CSRC’s focus on the level of regional market development and the legal environment in assessing IPO applications affected regional access to IPO resources. Our empirical results show that regions that displayed a higher level of enthusiasm for the reform did not receive higher IPO quotas than other regions, and that the CSRC did not enforce its reform regulation.

    Taking into account the timeliness of policy commitments, we consider that the CSRC may have implemented its regulation a relatively short time after re-opening the IPO system. Because certain regions may have benefited more than others in the first few months, we narrow our study period to the IPO-GROW1 period, which runs from June 19, 2006 to December 31, 2006. However, our results show that the effect of regional enthusiasm is still insignificant and the coefficient is negative. Furthermore, we conclude that the CSRC’s IPO policy was only a symbolic call and that the policy was never implemented.

    Robustness Check

    The effect of the IPO policy can also be reflected in the amount of funds raised in the capital market. Listed companies that raise funds can expand their operations, thereby providing more employment opportunities and contributing more local tax revenue. We use the amount of funds raised by a company to measure IPO-GROW.

    Table 8 shows that the level of enthusiasm for the reform in a region did not have an impact on the size of the IPO quota awarded. The results of our robustness test are in line with our previous test results.

    The main explanatory variable is regional enthusiasm, which is measured by the market value of the listed companies which had completed the share reform by June 18, 2006. We use alternative variables to test the robustness of this result. Since the IPO application and approval stages took a certain amount of time, we adopt an alternative regional enthusiasm measure based on the market value of listed companies which had completed the share reform process by December 31, 2005. Table 9 presents the test results, which show that the CSRC did not give a higher IPO quota to reform-active areas.

    Test of Rejected Companies

    We use multivariate OLS regression Model 2 to test whether the CSRC considered regional enthusiasm for the reform process when examining IPO applications21The explanatory variables for Model 2 are the same as in Model 1 with the exception of REGION-OWN. Since the CSRC takes into account the number of listed companies based in the local region when reviewing applications, we adopt the REGION-OWN variable. REGION-OWN is measured by the number of listed companies based in the region as a proportion of the total number of listed companies in the Chinese capital market.:

    Table 10 shows that only the market index (MARKET) and degree of IPO resources owned by areas (REGION_OWN) variables had a significant impact. Developed areas gained more listings and the regression results are not affected.

    Table 11 reports that a high level of regional enthusiasm for the reform process did not reduce the likelihood of applications being rejected. Nor did market process, economic development level, or the number of listed companies affect the CSRC’s decision. When deciding whether to approve a listing application, the CSRC mainly considers the circumstances of the company, such as its financial status and corporate governance. Thus, we conclude that active reform areas were not given favorable treatment by the CSRC.

    Taking into account the timeliness of IPO policy in the share reform, we consider that the CSRC may have tilted toward active regions. We therefore narrow the study window to the June 19, 2006 to December 31, 2006 period. Our regression results show that the pace of reform and the level of economic development did not significantly affect the adoption rate. The study window for IPO-REJECT1 runs from June 19, 2006 to December 31, 2006.

    Robustness Check

    The main explanatory variable for the test model is regional enthusiasm, which is measured by the market value of the listed companies which had completed the share reform process by June 18, 2006. We use an alternative variable measured by the market value of the listed companies which had completed the reform by December 31, 2005 to test the robustness of our results. The study window for IPO-REJECT1 runs from June 19, 2006 to December 31, 2006. Table 12 shows that the test results are basically unchanged and that the success or otherwise of listing applications was not affected by the pace of reform.

    The unit for the above test is an individual region. We adopt an alternative unit of measurement and conduct the logistic regression using the explanatory variable “IPO or not.” The results remain basically unchanged.

    4.2. Test of the CSRC’s SEO Policy

    We use another multivariate OLS regression to test whether listed companies that actively implemented the share reform obtained SEO quotas. The OLS regression model to be estimated is specified as follows22Obtaining data on rejected SEO applications gives us two better choices. Firstly, when testing whether applications made by companies active in the reform process were approved more readily, we are inclined to use the sample consisting of both rejected companies and approved companies. Secondly, even where listed companies met the minimum profitability requirement for issuing additional shares, more profitable companies may have been given priority to refinance. For these reasons, we should control for the effect of company profitability if data on rejected companies and the year of rejection become available.:

    SEO is a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the listed company was refinanced, and 0 otherwise.

    For companies that had been refinanced, we use a duration model to test whether companies that completed the reform process at an earlier stage were more likely to be awarded an SEO quota earlier23The 190 SEO companies in the sample include three listed financial companies: Shanghai Pudong Development Bank (600000), Minsheng Bank (600016), and CITIC Securities (600030). Since the profitability of financial companies is calculated in a different manner, our test of profitability (AVEROA) excludes all three financial companies in the SEO sample..

    SEO is a continuous variable in this equation. SEO is measured by the number of months from the date the refinancing was opened to the date of the refinancing.

    Tables 13 and 14 show that the probability of being refinanced and the batch are significantly negatively correlated. At the same time, the time required for the SEO application and the batch have a significantly positive correlation. The test results are in line with our hypotheses.

    Table 15 indicates that listed companies with a higher level of enthusiasm (smaller batch) needed less time to complete the reform and were able to secure an SEO quota more easily. Furthermore, the earlier the company completed the reform, the earlier it secured an SEO quota24The share reform process was initiated on April 29, 2005 and the first refinancing was completed on May 18, 2006. Companies had to wait for more than six months before refinancing even if they had completed the reform process. Refinancing was postponed during this six-month period. Companies that completed the reform process later were able to secure an SEO quota earlier if the CSRC did not consider the level of enthusiasm for the reform process at all.. To qualify for a refinancing, companies usually sought to speed up the reform process by paying a higher compensation rate. State-owned companies were able to obtain SEO resources more easily than private companies, although the coefficient is not significant.

    Taking into account the timeliness of SEO policy commitments, we consider that the CSRC is likely to have enforced its regulation within a relatively short time after reopening an SEO. If a large number of listed companies completed the reform, the CSRC was bound to weaken the policy incentives available. For this reason, we divide the study period into two periods: period I (2005.04.29 - 2005.12.31), and period II (2006.01.01 - 2006.06.18). Table 16 reports the test results.

    During period I, applications made by companies active in the reform process were readily approved. Earlier completion of the share reform process and a higher compensation rate ensured that listed companies secured an SEO quota at an earlier date. During period II, although applications made by companies active in the reform process were also readily approved, the date on which they qualified for refinancing was not affected by the reform completion date. As the reform process wore on, an increasing number of companies satisfied the conditions for SEOs. In allocating refinancing resources, the CSRC did not attach great importance to the level of enthusiasm for the reform.

    Robustness Check

    As noted above, the level of enthusiasm for the reform among listed companies is measured by the adjusted batch. We use the period the company took to complete the reform process as a sensitivity check25This refers to the length of time from the completion of the share reform to the date of the SEO policy announcement, and is measured in months.. The results are as follows:

    In contrast with the results shown in Tables 15 and 16, the results shown in Tables 17 and 18 are relatively stable. The refinancing needs of companies that completed the reform process at an early date were met before those of others. Companies that paid a higher compensation rate gained access to SEOs at an early date. The results of our robustness checks support our hypotheses.

    Test of Quality of Reformed Company

    The CSRC’s SEO policy gave a great reform incentive to listed companies. The previous test shows that companies that actively implemented the reform were given SEO quotas at an earlier date. Nevertheless, two important questions remain: did the CSRC’s SEO policy induce listed companies to engage in opportunistic behavior, and did some low-quality companies qualify for SEOs by accelerating the reform process? Toanswer these questions, we compare the quality of listed companies before and after the share reform.

    The test results described above do not take into account whether average ROA over the previous three years affected the length of time needed to gain an SEO quota. We examine the quality of listed companies in terms of discretionary accruals, the type of audit opinion received, and legal and regulatory violations. One of the major reasons companies receive non-standard audit opinions is poor corporate governance. A sound governance structure can reduce the likelihood that a listed company will receive a nonstandard audit opinion (Wang and Peng, 2007). Corporate law mandates that companies operate in a lawful manner and that board of directors, supervisors, and managers be honest and trustworthy. When a company is punished by the CSRC for a regulatory violation, it casts doubt on whether the company is operated in a normal manner and calls into question its quality.

    We classify the 190 listed companies that refinanced during the study period into four categories, A, B, C, and D, in terms of “completion time” and “implementation time.”

    Table 19 lists the specific classifications for the SEO sample. 124 companies which completed the reform process in 2005 secured SEOs, while only 66 companies were refinanced in 2006. Companies that completed the reform process at an early stage were awarded more SEO quotas, a result that accords with “early reform-oriented policies.”To avoid excessive concentration offinancing pressure in the market and stabilize market expectations, only 41 companies implemented refinancing in 2006, and 83 in 2007. Table 19 indicates that most of the companies which completed the share reform in 2006 were awarded SEO quotas in 2007.

    Table 20 shows that there is no significant difference between the earnings quality of companies which completed the reform process in 2005 and those that completed the reform process in 2006.

    Table 21 presents the distributions of non-standard audit opinions and listed company penalty cases resulting from violations in the SEO year and the previous year. We are unable to conduct a Chi-square test due to small sample size; the statistics we give are descriptive.

    Only one company which completed the reform process in 2005 was issued with a non-standard audit opinion. By comparison, 4 companies which completed the reform process in 2006 were issued with a non-standard audit opinion. Category A is the best in terms of audit opinions, because no company in this category was issued with a non-standard audit opinion in either the SEO year or the previous year. Category D is the worst in terms of corporate governance, with 4 companies being issued with nonstandard audit opinions.

    The distribution of penalty cases shows that companies in categories A, B, and C were operated legitimately and properly over the previous three years. Only one company in category D was punished by the CSRC for failing to disclose important information in a timely manner. Both the audit opinion and penalty case data provide evidence consistent with the earnings quality data. There is no significant difference between the early reform companies and the companies that reformed at a later date.

    Test of the Economic Consequences of the SEO Regulation

    The CSRC enforced the SEO regulation among listed companies in the course of the share reform. Since the SEO regulation served as an arrangement, it may bring certain economic consequences. We also pay close attention to the impact of the regulation on the allocation of the following resources.

    First of all, we test for the ROA of listed companies in the SEO year. Table 22 reports profitability among the four categories offirms. The average ROAs for companies which completed the reform process in 2005 and 2006 are 6.3% and 5.8%, respectively, with no significant difference between the two. Among the companies that implemented SEOs in 2006, the average ROA for category A firms was 6.0% and the average ROA for category C firms was 8.6%, with no significant difference. Among the companies that implemented SEOs in 2007, the average ROA for category B firms was 7.3% and the average ROA for category D firms was 7.0%, with the difference remaining insignificant.These results show there was no significant difference in the profitability of companies in the early and late reform groups.

    We further examine discretionary accruals in the SEO year as an extra measure of listed company quality. The results shown in Table 23 indicate that there was no significant difference in discretionary accruals between early and late reformers. We conclude that the CSRC’s SEO regulation did not affect resource allocation efficiency in the stock market.

    5. Conclusions and Limitations

    In the context of the transitional economy of the Chinese mainland, we investigate the efficiency of different forms of government regulation. We find that when theentity being regulated is complex and the regulation itself is implemented in the absence of explicit rules, regulation is ineffective, and that when the regulation is brief, concentrated, forceful, and highly focused, it does not necessarily induce the problem of opportunism.

    Taking the CSRC regulations implemented among companies and across different regions in the course of the share reform as an example, the complexity involved in implementing the share reform in different regions led to very high operating costs, and the CSRC did not have explicit criteria for assessing the level of enthusiasm with which different regions implemented the share reform. It was also difficult for local governments to assess to what extent the CSRC emphasized the reform. As a result, the CSRC did not take into account the enthusiasm shown by different regions in allocating IPO quotas. These problems made the regulation redundant. The CSRC did not award higher IPO quotas to more passive areas. We also find that corporations that completed the share reform process at an earlier stage secured refinancing quotas more easily. The CSRC seems to have assessed the degree of devotion shown by individual corporations in the share reform. It delivered on its SEO policy commitment to listed corporations and implemented the regulation effectively. Nor did the CSRC relax its standards when awarding SEO quotas to corporations that completed the share reform process earlier.The quality of corporations that completed the share reform was comparable to that of other firms, indicating that the CSRC regulation did not affect the efficiency of the capital market. In the SEO year, the difference between the quality of corporations that completed the share reform earlier and later was not significant.

    This paper provides empirical evidence on the efficiency of government regulation implemented subject to different constraints. Our study is helpful to understand the efficiency and limitations of government regulation in a transitional economy and in assessing how governments can improve the effectiveness of their regulations. It is also of interest to accounting and financial researchers in that a company’s accounting and financial decisions can be influenced by government regulation at any time.

    Our study has a number of limitations. First, our sample size is too small for an examination of the effect of CSRC IPO policy across regions. Due to our focus on regional activism in implementing the share reform, our regional sample is limited to the 31 Chinese provinces, autonomous regions, and municipalities. This may influence the robustness of our conclusions. Second, hidden regulatory policy may exist, which means that we may not have considered all applicable regulatory requirements. Third, while the benefits of regulation are clear, the costs of regulation can sometimes be obscure. Although we do not find that regulation induced opportunistic earnings management, this does not necessarily mean that the benefits of regulation outweigh the costs. This is an issue that is outside the scope of this paper. These limitations should be addressed and resolved in future research.

    Chen, D., Zhang, T., Xiang, L., 2008. Law environment, government regulation and implicit contract: empirical evidences from the scandals of Chinese listed companies. Economic Research Journal 3, 60-72. (In Chinese)

    Chen X., Ye, P., Chen, D., 2003. Opportunistic restructuring and regulation rigidity. Economic Research Journal 5, 13-22. (In Chinese)

    Chung S., 2002. Homeless or home owner: the intention and consequence of rental regulation (in Chinese). In: Economics Interpretations, Commercial Press, Beijing.

    Glaeser, E., Shleifer, A., 2000. Legal origins. Mimeo, Harvard University.

    Glaeser, E., Shleifer, A., 2001. A case for quantity regulation. Harvard Institute of Economic Research Paper No. 1909, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Institute of Economic Research.

    Glaeser, E., Shleifer, A., 2003. The rise of the regulatory state. Journal of Economic Literature XLI, 401-425.

    Hay, J., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., 1996. Toward a theory of legal reform. European Economic Review 40, 559-567.

    Jin, Q., Yuan, H., 2005. Corporate governance and consideration of the Share Reform. Working Paper. (In Chinese)

    La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silane, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., 1998. The quality of government. NBER Working Paper 6727, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Li, D., 2001. Principal shareholder control, earnings management and underperformance of the listed companies. Doctoral Thesis, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics. (In Chinese)

    Li, X., 2005. Government regulation: ever-existing controversy and practical choice. Academic Forum 7, 19-22. (In Chinese)

    Mao, M., 2007. A review of the researches of government regulation. Management World 2, 137-150. (In Chinese)

    Pistor, K., Xu, C., 2002. Law enforcement under incomplete law: theory and evidence from financial market regulation. Mimeo, Columbia Law School.

    Shleifer, A., 2005. Understanding regulation. European Financial Management 11(4), 439-451.

    Stigler, G. J., Friedland, C., 1962. What can regulators regulate? The case of electricity. Journal of Law and Economics 5(1), 1-16.

    Stigler, G. J., 1971. The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2(1), 3-21.

    Sun, C., 2004. The analysis and implications of the evolution of American government regulation. Nanjing Social Science 1, 36-41. (In Chinese)

    Wang, H., 2004. Loosing or enhancing the regulation - the route of Chinese government regulation in the new era. Jiangsu Social Science 3, 103-111. (In Chinese)

    Wang, Z., Peng, J., 2007. Relevance of China’s governance structure of listed companies and the audit opinion. Audit and Economy Research 6, 16-19. (In Chinese)

    Wu, C., Zheng, F., Lin, Z., Li, W., Wu, S., 2008. A theoretical and empirical study on what affect consideration ratio for Split Share Structure Reform of listed companies in China. Economic Research Journal 8, 14-22. (In Chinese)

    Yang, D., 2003. Research on the shell resources of listed companies and IPO pricing. Doctoral Thesis, Southwestern University of Finance and Economics. (In Chinese)

    Zhu, X., Dong, L., 2005. Behavior deviation and system change in transitional economy. Economic Problems 7, 7-8. (In Chinese)

    * This paper is supported by the National Natural Science Fund (grant no. 70602011) and the National Social Science Fund (grant no. 08CJY009).We also appreciate the support we have

    from the IAPHD Project of Nanjing University, the Institution of Accounting and Finance of Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, Research Project 985 of the Institution of Economic Transition and Development of Nanjing University, and the discussion at the 2008 summer seminar of City University of Hong Kong. We give our special thanks to Charles Jieping Chen, Xijia Su, Shimin Chen, Bin Ke, Oliver Zhen Li, Xiongsheng Yang, Yuetang Wang, Zengquan Li, Liansheng Wu, Xi Wu, and Xing Xiao for their valuable comments and advice. We thank the anonymous referees for their constructive suggestions.

    ** Corresponding author. E-mail address: sufechen@263.net. Correspondence address: Research Institute of Accounting and Finance, Nanjing University, Nanjing, China, 210093.

    久久久久久久久久成人| 五月玫瑰六月丁香| h日本视频在线播放| 久久精品国产亚洲av天美| 丝袜脚勾引网站| 欧美bdsm另类| 美女脱内裤让男人舔精品视频| 日本欧美视频一区| 国产精品99久久99久久久不卡 | 欧美亚洲 丝袜 人妻 在线| 人妻 亚洲 视频| 亚洲欧美一区二区三区国产| 成人漫画全彩无遮挡| 少妇人妻 视频| 欧美区成人在线视频| 国产免费又黄又爽又色| 春色校园在线视频观看| 爱豆传媒免费全集在线观看| 大话2 男鬼变身卡| 一本一本久久a久久精品综合妖精| 飞空精品影院首页| 曰老女人黄片| 国精品久久久久久国模美| 在线av久久热| 青草久久国产| 国产欧美亚洲国产| 亚洲国产成人一精品久久久| 欧美精品啪啪一区二区三区 | 久久这里只有精品19| 黄色视频,在线免费观看| 精品国产一区二区三区四区第35| 国产亚洲av高清不卡| 久久99热这里只频精品6学生| 久久精品亚洲av国产电影网| 老司机影院毛片| 欧美午夜高清在线| 丝瓜视频免费看黄片| 亚洲一区中文字幕在线| 一区二区三区四区激情视频| av网站在线播放免费| 超色免费av| 亚洲中文av在线| 久久精品aⅴ一区二区三区四区| 亚洲全国av大片| 下体分泌物呈黄色| 国产日韩一区二区三区精品不卡| 国产麻豆69| 日韩大码丰满熟妇| 51午夜福利影视在线观看| 99国产精品免费福利视频| 国产亚洲精品第一综合不卡| 国产视频一区二区在线看| 国产av国产精品国产| 亚洲国产欧美在线一区| 成年人黄色毛片网站| 精品免费久久久久久久清纯 | 国产欧美日韩一区二区三区在线| 国产国语露脸激情在线看| 国产福利在线免费观看视频| 岛国毛片在线播放| 一个人免费看片子| 日韩中文字幕欧美一区二区| 精品久久久精品久久久| 免费久久久久久久精品成人欧美视频| 免费在线观看黄色视频的| 久久天躁狠狠躁夜夜2o2o| 亚洲精品粉嫩美女一区| 精品一品国产午夜福利视频| 欧美亚洲日本最大视频资源| a 毛片基地| 精品高清国产在线一区| 国产片内射在线| 在线av久久热| 久久久国产成人免费| 国产精品久久久久久人妻精品电影 | 叶爱在线成人免费视频播放| 考比视频在线观看| 精品人妻1区二区| 国产日韩欧美视频二区| 中文字幕高清在线视频| 9色porny在线观看| 国产97色在线日韩免费| 日韩有码中文字幕| 这个男人来自地球电影免费观看| 黄色视频不卡| 精品视频人人做人人爽| 97在线人人人人妻| 18禁观看日本| 日韩一区二区三区影片| 在线十欧美十亚洲十日本专区| 国产99久久九九免费精品| 欧美一级毛片孕妇| 成人国产av品久久久| 国产一区有黄有色的免费视频| 手机成人av网站| 日日爽夜夜爽网站| 国产麻豆69| 成在线人永久免费视频| 国产精品久久久人人做人人爽| 日本五十路高清| 麻豆乱淫一区二区| 欧美人与性动交α欧美软件| 一区二区三区乱码不卡18| 欧美国产精品一级二级三级| 狂野欧美激情性xxxx| 亚洲国产av新网站| 别揉我奶头~嗯~啊~动态视频 | 搡老乐熟女国产| 大香蕉久久成人网| 少妇裸体淫交视频免费看高清 | xxxhd国产人妻xxx| 亚洲综合色网址| 日本一区二区免费在线视频| 亚洲av欧美aⅴ国产| 精品国产一区二区三区久久久樱花| 一二三四社区在线视频社区8| 国产xxxxx性猛交| 一区二区三区激情视频| 777久久人妻少妇嫩草av网站| 国产亚洲精品一区二区www | 久久精品亚洲熟妇少妇任你| 一级毛片女人18水好多| 成人18禁高潮啪啪吃奶动态图| 99久久精品国产亚洲精品| 制服诱惑二区| 亚洲国产欧美一区二区综合| 精品国产乱码久久久久久男人| 亚洲性夜色夜夜综合| 欧美黑人欧美精品刺激| 欧美老熟妇乱子伦牲交| 在线观看免费视频网站a站| 新久久久久国产一级毛片| www.自偷自拍.com| 又紧又爽又黄一区二区| 黑人巨大精品欧美一区二区mp4| 亚洲av成人一区二区三| 日本撒尿小便嘘嘘汇集6| 成在线人永久免费视频| 天天影视国产精品| 亚洲专区中文字幕在线| 丰满饥渴人妻一区二区三| 亚洲欧美精品综合一区二区三区| 成年人午夜在线观看视频| 超碰成人久久| 午夜日韩欧美国产| 人人澡人人妻人| 欧美久久黑人一区二区| 亚洲av电影在线观看一区二区三区| 午夜激情久久久久久久| 久久久久久亚洲精品国产蜜桃av| 亚洲人成电影观看| 亚洲精品久久久久久婷婷小说| av网站免费在线观看视频| 91av网站免费观看| 久久中文字幕一级| 中文字幕另类日韩欧美亚洲嫩草| 亚洲av电影在线进入| 人人妻人人澡人人爽人人夜夜| 老司机影院毛片| 99精国产麻豆久久婷婷| 99精国产麻豆久久婷婷| 亚洲中文av在线| 精品久久久久久久毛片微露脸 | 亚洲精品美女久久久久99蜜臀| 欧美精品高潮呻吟av久久| 巨乳人妻的诱惑在线观看| 精品亚洲乱码少妇综合久久| 国产日韩欧美在线精品| 免费少妇av软件| 新久久久久国产一级毛片| 久久久久久久国产电影| 亚洲国产欧美日韩在线播放| 亚洲熟女毛片儿| 麻豆乱淫一区二区| 亚洲中文字幕日韩| 九色亚洲精品在线播放| 一级a爱视频在线免费观看| 亚洲精品一卡2卡三卡4卡5卡 | 丝袜脚勾引网站| 国产精品久久久久久精品电影小说| 亚洲精品一卡2卡三卡4卡5卡 | 自线自在国产av| 久久久久久久大尺度免费视频| 伊人久久大香线蕉亚洲五| 老熟女久久久| 亚洲全国av大片| 日韩欧美国产一区二区入口| av天堂在线播放| 天天躁夜夜躁狠狠躁躁| 天天躁夜夜躁狠狠躁躁| 97在线人人人人妻| 国产精品麻豆人妻色哟哟久久| 中文字幕制服av| 自线自在国产av| 久久久国产欧美日韩av| 午夜福利乱码中文字幕| 18禁国产床啪视频网站| 亚洲男人天堂网一区| 日韩视频一区二区在线观看| 亚洲七黄色美女视频| 久久久久久久久久久久大奶| 18在线观看网站| 久久性视频一级片| 视频区图区小说| 女人精品久久久久毛片| 亚洲avbb在线观看| 男女国产视频网站| 亚洲欧美清纯卡通| a 毛片基地| 韩国精品一区二区三区| 在线观看一区二区三区激情| 天天影视国产精品| 久久久欧美国产精品| 中文字幕另类日韩欧美亚洲嫩草| 人成视频在线观看免费观看| 又大又爽又粗| 久久精品亚洲av国产电影网| 黄色片一级片一级黄色片| 十分钟在线观看高清视频www| 中文欧美无线码| 精品一区二区三卡| 国产成人精品无人区| 久久99一区二区三区| 国产精品秋霞免费鲁丝片| 亚洲人成77777在线视频| 大香蕉久久网| 精品国产乱码久久久久久男人| 美女大奶头黄色视频| 免费高清在线观看视频在线观看| 久久香蕉激情| 国产麻豆69| 国产男女内射视频| 97在线人人人人妻| 新久久久久国产一级毛片| 美女午夜性视频免费| 久久天堂一区二区三区四区| 国产精品九九99| 狠狠婷婷综合久久久久久88av| 黄频高清免费视频| 欧美在线一区亚洲| 免费人妻精品一区二区三区视频| 亚洲天堂av无毛| 国产一区二区在线观看av| av又黄又爽大尺度在线免费看| 免费av中文字幕在线| 国产一区二区 视频在线| 王馨瑶露胸无遮挡在线观看| 水蜜桃什么品种好| 激情视频va一区二区三区| 18禁观看日本| 久久精品国产亚洲av香蕉五月 | 国产精品久久久人人做人人爽| 美女高潮喷水抽搐中文字幕| 亚洲人成77777在线视频| 1024视频免费在线观看| 一区二区av电影网| 亚洲欧洲日产国产| 一区二区三区四区激情视频| 五月天丁香电影| 亚洲精品第二区| 亚洲av成人不卡在线观看播放网 | 老司机影院毛片| a级毛片在线看网站| 精品熟女少妇八av免费久了| 久久久久久久久免费视频了| av国产精品久久久久影院| 精品国产乱子伦一区二区三区 | 成人国产一区最新在线观看| 亚洲第一av免费看| 精品视频人人做人人爽| 成年人免费黄色播放视频| 91av网站免费观看| 91国产中文字幕| 99热网站在线观看| 欧美另类一区| 日日爽夜夜爽网站| 女性被躁到高潮视频| 性色av一级| 国产精品久久久av美女十八| 国产不卡av网站在线观看| 91精品三级在线观看| 19禁男女啪啪无遮挡网站| 亚洲精品中文字幕一二三四区 | 精品亚洲乱码少妇综合久久| 欧美av亚洲av综合av国产av| 午夜福利一区二区在线看| 亚洲久久久国产精品| 国产91精品成人一区二区三区 | 日韩欧美一区二区三区在线观看 | 一区二区三区激情视频| 狠狠精品人妻久久久久久综合| 在线观看一区二区三区激情| 日韩熟女老妇一区二区性免费视频| 久久天躁狠狠躁夜夜2o2o| 18禁裸乳无遮挡动漫免费视频| 人人妻人人添人人爽欧美一区卜| 在线十欧美十亚洲十日本专区| 欧美成人午夜精品| av天堂在线播放| 99精品欧美一区二区三区四区| 狠狠婷婷综合久久久久久88av| 麻豆国产av国片精品| 亚洲国产中文字幕在线视频| 黄色毛片三级朝国网站| 麻豆乱淫一区二区| 国产亚洲av片在线观看秒播厂| 另类亚洲欧美激情| 欧美日韩亚洲综合一区二区三区_| 一级,二级,三级黄色视频| 精品一区二区三区四区五区乱码| 久久ye,这里只有精品| 在线观看舔阴道视频| 久久久久久免费高清国产稀缺| 日本欧美视频一区| 99国产精品免费福利视频| 纵有疾风起免费观看全集完整版| 亚洲一卡2卡3卡4卡5卡精品中文| 日本猛色少妇xxxxx猛交久久| 9191精品国产免费久久| 一边摸一边做爽爽视频免费| 老熟妇仑乱视频hdxx| tube8黄色片| 精品人妻熟女毛片av久久网站| 中亚洲国语对白在线视频| 性少妇av在线| 久久午夜综合久久蜜桃| 国产精品熟女久久久久浪| 国产欧美日韩一区二区三区在线| 美女中出高潮动态图| 老司机影院毛片| 制服诱惑二区| 欧美另类一区| 欧美人与性动交α欧美软件| 飞空精品影院首页| 蜜桃在线观看..| 国产免费一区二区三区四区乱码| 超碰97精品在线观看| 日本欧美视频一区| 五月开心婷婷网| 男女边摸边吃奶| 成人国语在线视频| 国产成人免费无遮挡视频| 亚洲欧美激情在线| 精品一品国产午夜福利视频| www.av在线官网国产| 最新的欧美精品一区二区| 亚洲成国产人片在线观看| 窝窝影院91人妻| 97精品久久久久久久久久精品| 国产成人系列免费观看| 亚洲av日韩精品久久久久久密| 大香蕉久久成人网| 人妻久久中文字幕网| 精品高清国产在线一区| 婷婷成人精品国产| 另类亚洲欧美激情| 满18在线观看网站| 亚洲精品日韩在线中文字幕| 久久久久国产一级毛片高清牌| 午夜91福利影院| 嫩草影视91久久| 日韩,欧美,国产一区二区三区| 国产成人影院久久av| 日韩制服骚丝袜av| 免费在线观看日本一区| 午夜两性在线视频| 久久精品国产亚洲av香蕉五月 | 亚洲精品在线美女| 久久精品国产亚洲av香蕉五月 | 丝袜美腿诱惑在线| 三级毛片av免费| 少妇猛男粗大的猛烈进出视频| 亚洲中文字幕日韩| 少妇被粗大的猛进出69影院| 亚洲七黄色美女视频| 十分钟在线观看高清视频www| 国产免费视频播放在线视频| 日韩中文字幕欧美一区二区| 日韩精品免费视频一区二区三区| 亚洲七黄色美女视频| 成人国语在线视频| 黑人操中国人逼视频| 亚洲精品一区蜜桃| 国产亚洲欧美在线一区二区| 欧美日韩视频精品一区| av天堂久久9| 久久人人爽人人片av| 久久狼人影院| 欧美精品一区二区大全| 狂野欧美激情性xxxx| 精品高清国产在线一区| 妹子高潮喷水视频| 精品一品国产午夜福利视频| 在线看a的网站| 午夜老司机福利片| 亚洲 欧美一区二区三区| 久久久久久免费高清国产稀缺| 精品人妻在线不人妻| 美女脱内裤让男人舔精品视频| 久久久国产成人免费| 脱女人内裤的视频| 狠狠精品人妻久久久久久综合| 国产不卡av网站在线观看| 电影成人av| www.精华液| 美国免费a级毛片| 国产野战对白在线观看| 女性生殖器流出的白浆| av福利片在线| 国精品久久久久久国模美| 啦啦啦啦在线视频资源| 黄片小视频在线播放| 亚洲av国产av综合av卡| 法律面前人人平等表现在哪些方面 | 十分钟在线观看高清视频www| 亚洲精品国产av成人精品| 十八禁高潮呻吟视频| 成人亚洲精品一区在线观看| 日本vs欧美在线观看视频| 99国产精品99久久久久| 国产深夜福利视频在线观看| 成人免费观看视频高清| 99精品久久久久人妻精品| 少妇猛男粗大的猛烈进出视频| 三上悠亚av全集在线观看| 国产亚洲欧美在线一区二区| 黄色片一级片一级黄色片| 91九色精品人成在线观看| 97在线人人人人妻| 亚洲人成77777在线视频| 一区二区av电影网| av在线播放精品| 午夜视频精品福利| 他把我摸到了高潮在线观看 | 一个人免费在线观看的高清视频 | 欧美日韩中文字幕国产精品一区二区三区 | 国产一区二区 视频在线| 91九色精品人成在线观看| 亚洲全国av大片| 五月开心婷婷网| 99久久国产精品久久久| 午夜日韩欧美国产| 久久精品国产a三级三级三级| 欧美激情高清一区二区三区| 成人国语在线视频| 午夜福利影视在线免费观看| 悠悠久久av| 欧美在线黄色| 中文字幕人妻丝袜制服| 国产男人的电影天堂91| 欧美日韩精品网址| 女性生殖器流出的白浆| 亚洲欧洲精品一区二区精品久久久| 天堂俺去俺来也www色官网| 一二三四在线观看免费中文在| 亚洲精品成人av观看孕妇| 美女高潮喷水抽搐中文字幕| 一区二区三区精品91| 中文字幕av电影在线播放| 人人妻,人人澡人人爽秒播| 精品免费久久久久久久清纯 | 中文字幕人妻熟女乱码| 丁香六月欧美| 男女午夜视频在线观看| 满18在线观看网站| 欧美国产精品一级二级三级| 久久人人爽人人片av| 黄色视频不卡| 十分钟在线观看高清视频www| 99国产精品一区二区三区| 国产精品国产av在线观看| 大香蕉久久成人网| 亚洲国产欧美网| 国产一区有黄有色的免费视频| 欧美日韩成人在线一区二区| 看免费av毛片| 午夜免费成人在线视频| 亚洲七黄色美女视频| 久久久精品94久久精品| 一边摸一边做爽爽视频免费| 久久久久精品人妻al黑| 一本—道久久a久久精品蜜桃钙片| 色老头精品视频在线观看| 国产欧美日韩一区二区三 | 热99re8久久精品国产| 超碰成人久久| 亚洲精品久久成人aⅴ小说| 两性夫妻黄色片| 精品高清国产在线一区| 久久人人97超碰香蕉20202| 高清黄色对白视频在线免费看| 久久国产精品人妻蜜桃| 18禁观看日本| 51午夜福利影视在线观看| 国产精品一区二区在线不卡| 亚洲精品国产av蜜桃| 免费女性裸体啪啪无遮挡网站| 大片电影免费在线观看免费| 亚洲三区欧美一区| 蜜桃在线观看..| 波多野结衣一区麻豆| 王馨瑶露胸无遮挡在线观看| 搡老岳熟女国产| 汤姆久久久久久久影院中文字幕| 啦啦啦在线免费观看视频4| www.自偷自拍.com| 亚洲七黄色美女视频| 午夜免费鲁丝| 黑人巨大精品欧美一区二区蜜桃| 美女脱内裤让男人舔精品视频| 欧美中文综合在线视频| netflix在线观看网站| 999精品在线视频| 国产一区二区三区综合在线观看| 青草久久国产| 热re99久久国产66热| 国产xxxxx性猛交| 国产欧美日韩一区二区精品| 精品久久久精品久久久| kizo精华| 99热网站在线观看| 一级黄色大片毛片| 成人亚洲精品一区在线观看| 各种免费的搞黄视频| 国产精品一区二区精品视频观看| 日韩,欧美,国产一区二区三区| 可以免费在线观看a视频的电影网站| 黄网站色视频无遮挡免费观看| 女人久久www免费人成看片| 少妇的丰满在线观看| av一本久久久久| 亚洲欧美成人综合另类久久久| 久久久久网色| 男女床上黄色一级片免费看| 免费在线观看黄色视频的| 老司机影院成人| 久久亚洲精品不卡| 成人黄色视频免费在线看| 丰满少妇做爰视频| 欧美激情 高清一区二区三区| 后天国语完整版免费观看| 欧美乱码精品一区二区三区| 日韩欧美一区视频在线观看| 成年人黄色毛片网站| 色视频在线一区二区三区| 亚洲国产欧美日韩在线播放| 亚洲国产精品一区二区三区在线| 精品少妇久久久久久888优播| 美女中出高潮动态图| 中文字幕人妻熟女乱码| 久久久久网色| 日本精品一区二区三区蜜桃| 99热国产这里只有精品6| 9热在线视频观看99| 国产在线免费精品| 欧美另类一区| 久久久久久久国产电影| 精品久久久久久久毛片微露脸 | 中文字幕色久视频| 精品一区二区三区av网在线观看 | 午夜91福利影院| h视频一区二区三区| 国产黄频视频在线观看| 两性午夜刺激爽爽歪歪视频在线观看 | 亚洲欧洲精品一区二区精品久久久| 不卡一级毛片| 成年美女黄网站色视频大全免费| 久久综合国产亚洲精品| 无遮挡黄片免费观看| 亚洲国产欧美一区二区综合| 91老司机精品| 一区福利在线观看| 十分钟在线观看高清视频www| 一级黄色大片毛片| 中文字幕另类日韩欧美亚洲嫩草| 9色porny在线观看| 丝袜喷水一区| 桃红色精品国产亚洲av| 99久久99久久久精品蜜桃| 国产又色又爽无遮挡免| 欧美中文综合在线视频| 在线观看免费视频网站a站| 欧美日韩亚洲国产一区二区在线观看 | 一二三四在线观看免费中文在| 久久人妻福利社区极品人妻图片| 老司机深夜福利视频在线观看 | 丝袜美足系列| videosex国产| 久久 成人 亚洲| 亚洲av日韩精品久久久久久密| 精品少妇内射三级| 国内毛片毛片毛片毛片毛片| 欧美人与性动交α欧美软件| 亚洲七黄色美女视频| 国产99久久九九免费精品| 午夜福利乱码中文字幕| 国产男女内射视频| 成年动漫av网址| 午夜老司机福利片| 国产亚洲一区二区精品| 久久久久国内视频| 下体分泌物呈黄色| 丝袜人妻中文字幕| 亚洲熟女毛片儿| 日韩有码中文字幕| 嫩草影视91久久| 夜夜夜夜夜久久久久| 午夜影院在线不卡| 2018国产大陆天天弄谢| 午夜福利视频精品| 老汉色av国产亚洲站长工具| 免费一级毛片在线播放高清视频 | 国产一区二区 视频在线| 一本一本久久a久久精品综合妖精| 国产精品一区二区免费欧美 |