• <tr id="yyy80"></tr>
  • <sup id="yyy80"></sup>
  • <tfoot id="yyy80"><noscript id="yyy80"></noscript></tfoot>
  • 99热精品在线国产_美女午夜性视频免费_国产精品国产高清国产av_av欧美777_自拍偷自拍亚洲精品老妇_亚洲熟女精品中文字幕_www日本黄色视频网_国产精品野战在线观看 ?

    Understanding Farmers’ Preferences Towards Insurance Schemes that Promote Biosecurity Best Management Practices

    2022-12-14 08:20:30RosaMatoAmboageJuliaTouzaMarioSoli

    Rosa Mato-Amboage 1 · Julia Touza 1,2 · Mario Soli?o 3,4

    Abstract Plant pest and disease outbreaks, which occur with increasing frequency and intensity, cause catastrophic losses and threaten food security in many areas around the world. These impacts are expected to be exacerbated by climate change. Tackling this challenge requires mechanisms that ensure the f inancial security of farmers while incentivizing private biosecurity eff orts to prevent future outbreaks.This study explored crop producers’ preferences for a subsidized insurance scheme as an instrument to manage novel biotic risks. Specif ically, we developed a choice experiment to evaluate Spanish growers’ willingness to pay for a crop insurance product that promotes compliance with best biosecurity management practices. Our results show that while growers are willing to pay more for high coverage products that increase the resilience of crops to potential catastrophic outbreaks, there is neither a strong demand nor widespread availability of such tools. Farmers required reductions in premiums before undertaking risk prevention measures; they are more willing to pay for schemes that link their eligibility to access to ad hoc funds in the eventuality of a catastrophic outbreak than they are to purchase insurance. Our f indings also suggest that Spanish growers prefer expanding the eligible risks covered by insurance and envisage a role for insurance in off ering biosecurity protection.

    Keywords Biosecurity protection · Choice experiment ·Crop insurance · Pest risk · Spain · Subsidized insurance

    1 Introduction

    Plant pest outbreaks, plant disease epidemics, and uncontrolled invasive species can result in signif icant losses in food crop production, which are ref lected in lower yields and outbreak-specif ic response strategies such as trade movement restrictions. These outbreaks can also cause disruptive impacts on ecosystem functions and human health, as well as knock on eff ects on trade relations that disrupt entire economic sectors (Pejchar and Mooney 2009; Savary et al.2019; Ristaino et al. 2021). Climate change and trade-related factors, including agriculture production specialization, are likely to aggravate the frequency of crop failure or destruction due to pest and disease outbreaks (Bebber et al. 2013;Perrings 2016). Therefore, we should expect new risk management tools to be developed that deal with such devastating events, and promote private biosecurity practices, which would gain importance in coming years (Bate et al. 2021;Vyas et al. 2021).

    Some studies have discussed innovative insurance schemes by treating the spread of invasive species as an insurable peril that would encourage prevention efforts(Liesivaara and Myyr? 2015; Epanchin-Niell 2017; Stoneham et al. 2021). For specif ic commodities, industry-led risk markets exist to manage biosecurity risks, although for catastrophic events related to outbreaks from quarantine or emerging plant pests, infectious diseases, and invasive non-native species, agricultural insurance markets are still not well developed. This leaves farmers dependent almost solely on ad hoc relief payments (Bielza Diaz-Caneja et al.2009; Bulut 2017). Major outbreaks cause problems for insurance markets because they are systemic in nature and insurers face asymmetric information problems (Miranda and Glauber 1997 ; Esuola et al. 2007). This means that insurance schemes often need support from the public sector to develop successful risk management strategies (Miranda and Glauber 1997; Goodwin 2001; Wright 2014). No private multi-peril insurance program has managed to survive without government support in Spain (Wright 2014). The question is: how can governments support a subsidized insurance to cover novel threats and to encourage growers’ biosecurity behavior? Hennessy ( 2008) and Beckie et al. ( 2019),for example, proposed insurance designs where those who comply with certain biosecurity management practices are entitled to receive linked reductions in premiums, or government compensation beyond a certain minimum level in the event of an outbreak. This article focuses on understanding crop producers’ preferences for some design attributes of a subsidized insurance for emerging pest and disease problems. Thus, we conducted a choice experiment (CE)to investigate Spanish farmer’s preferences for or against a subsidized insurance that covers emergent plant pest and disease risks, something currently is not off ered in Spain,as an incentive policy to achieve higher biosecurity through requiring compliance with certain production practices.

    There is a large literature that explores factors that aff ect farmers demand for crop insurance by using stated preference approaches such as CE, with an increasing interest in investigating the eff ect of farmers’ characteristics on purchasing decisions and their willingness to pay (WTP)for extreme weather-related insurance, particularly in lowincome countries (Budhathoki et al. 2019; Doherty et al.2021; Vyas et al. 2021). Recent studies that also have a focus on investigating preferences about insurance attributes include: (1) Liesivaara and Myyra ( 2017), who used a choice experiment to evaluate the WTP of farmers to buy crop insurance in Finland, showing the eff ect of farmers’expectation regarding support by the government with ad hoc payments; (2) The CE analysis conducted in Denmark by J?rgensen et al. ( 2020) for an insurance product where land management practices to improve soil sustainability is a precondition for obtaining access to climate risk-related insurance. J?rgensen et al. found that farmers whose farms have poor quality soils were more likely to purchase insurance; (3) Huang et al. ( 2020) examined preferences for multiple- perils insurance and showed that farmers who have suff ered insect, pest, or plant disease damages are willing to pay a high premium for an insurance with a high minimum compensation ratio for production loss and multiple crops covered; and (4) Our article contributes to this literature by focusing on novel biotic risks to growers, and evaluates farmer preferences for alternative crop insurance products that provide protection from emerging pests and diseases.Our analysis therefore contributes to the limited literature that examines social preferences over the role of designing agricultural insurance to incentivize on-farm biosecurity(Beckie et al. 2019; Vyas et al. 2021). In particular, we focus on exploring the potential role of cost-sharing arrangements between the private and public sectors (that is, governments,industry, and farmers) in designing an insurance scheme that can contribute to higher farmer uptake.

    The results of this study show that there is limited demand for crop insurance, even though farmers prefer insurance products with full coverage, including novel pests and diseases. Linking government ad hoc compensation payments to the purchase of insurance through a co-payment can act as an additional incentive for insurance uptake. We also explored the eff ects of requiring additional biosecurity-related production measures, and found that farmers negatively react to purchase of an insurance if biosecurity constraints are mandatory.

    The next section presents crop insurance in Spain as case study. Section 3 describes the hypothetical insurance scheme used in the choice experiment as well as our modelling approach. The results of the survey are presented in Sect. 4,while in Sect. 5 we discuss the results, and our conclusions are off ered in Sect. 6.

    2 Case Study: Crop Insurance in Spain

    Agricultural insurance in Spain, founded in 1978, is an example of subsidized schemes based on joint participation between public and private institutions. It is considered one of the most advanced crop insurance systems in the EU (OECD 2011). It is voluntary, and the participation of private insurance companies is achieved through a coinsurance pooling scheme in which insurance companies market the products, and the governmental insurance agency subsidizes the premium and provides reinsurance. The State Entity for Agricultural Insurance (ENESA), an autonomous body linked to the Ministry of the Environment and Rural and Marine Aff airs (MAPAMA), acts as the policy-making body. The ENESA creates the Annual Plan of Agricultural Insurance Policies, which determines the level of subsidies and establishes the technical conditions of insurance policies. Agroseguro is a private company that participates in the scheme, is in charge of administering the insurance policies and claims, and conducts the statistical and actuarial research. Farmers pay Agroseguro the net of the insurance subsidy, and Agroseguro collects the subsidy directly from ENESA and the government.

    Since the insurance program has been established, farmers cover between 35 and 55% of the insurance premium,and autonomous communities in some years subsidize up to nearly 20% of the remaining cost of insurance; the remainder is subsidized by Agroseguro (Agroseguro 2015). Despite the high subsidization, the total liability of crop insurance is still roughly 35% of the total insurable agricultural output, and the size of the program is still modest compared to the total economic size of the sector (OECD 2011). It is important to note that this hybrid insurance market is thought to have limited the scope of ad hoc and ex post assistance (OECD 2011).

    Currently, agricultural, livestock, forestry, and aquaculture production are covered against most of the climate risks that may aff ect them. However, pest and disease damage to crops is not covered. By using as an entry point the ongoing struggles to eradicate a recently introduced potato pest,Tecia solanivora, in northern Spain (EPPO Global Database 2015), we hope to gather data that will assist in the design of new insurance policies to manage comprehensive multiperil risks.

    Our case study targeted crop producers in the region of Galicia, northwest Spain. The reason for concentrating on a particular regional jurisdiction was the fact that the structure of subsidized insurance payments is partly determined at the regional level, as is the creation of ad hoc compensation payments. In Galicia, only 2% of the cultivated area is currently insured, making it the region with the lowest percentage of insured cultivated area in the country, despite having a strong agroeconomic sector (Agroseguro 2015). The area is mostly rural, with many farmers characterized as “hard to reach” due to their remote location, old age, and limited educational background (Rodriguez-Couso et al. 2006).Many farmers in the region practice multiple cropping and have relatively small holdings. Currently available insurance policies are often not designed with this consumer type in mind and, in order to enhance small farm participation in insurance, there is a need to better understand farmer needs(European Commission 2018). Insurance has the additional benef it that, by focusing on an area where a rare but potentially very damaging pest outbreak is occurring, respondents would, in principle, be aware of such extreme risks and not underestimate them.

    3 Methods

    In our analysis, we assume that a farmer’s decision to opt for a given insurance contract is determined by the relative utility he can gain by choosing the contract (characterized by its attributes) compared to choosing no insurance. Data were collected using a choice experiment (CE) to elicit farmers’preferences. One advantage of CE is that it is possible to value hypothetical changes in goods and services (Johnston et al. 2017). Thus, CE was used because there are no available crop insurance markets that off er coverage for pest and disease risks in Spain.

    3.1 Attributes and Levels

    Each choice alternative consisted of f ive attributes: coverage, production requirements, deductible, government copayment option, and insurance premium. The attributes and their levels are partially based on Heikkil? et al. ( 2016),Liesivaara and Myyr? ( 2014), Civic Consulting ( 2006),and Asseldonk et al. ( 2006). The levels of the attributes and the attribute combinations (and therefore the products off ered) are hypothetical; however, they were all set at realistic ranges, based on the literature of European insurance schemes cited in Sect. 2 and similarities to existing insurance products. The description of the attributes and levels is included in Table 1.

    An insurance scheme should incentivize producers who purchase insurance to take risk prevention measures thereafter. The attribute “production requirements” evaluates the trade-off s faced by farmers on biosecurity risk reduction eff orts. Some farmers may be willing to adopt costly enhanced biosecurity measures compared with the national standard in return for having a lower insurance premium,or vice versa.

    Another insurance characteristic is the “l(fā)evel of coverage”that the insurance product provides. Increasing the coverage raises the premiums, but it also means a better safety net for farmers. Previous studies concluded that farmers are often not willing to purchase insurance that covers extensive losses (Asseldonk et al. 2006). In order to explore preferences for comprehensive insurance, in particular that which also off ers coverage against potential catastrophic emerging plant pests and diseases, we identif ied three incremental levels of coverage (Table 1).

    The “deductible” is the minimum percentage of the loss in production value required to take a claim into consideration. It is a crucial part of insurance schemes, as it reduces moral hazard and incentivizes disease prevention and good practices by growers. In current crop insurance products,this percentage is variable depending, for example, on the type of risk, but it is often set at 30% (Mercadé et al. 2009).

    Government support of crop insurance is described through two mechanisms: the already subsidized premium amounts in the Spanish insurance market, and an additional payment to cover part of the deductible amount of those insured during catastrophic events (including climate-related catastrophes or pests or diseases of great risk that can also lead to catastrophic consequences and that require special biosecurity control measures to limit further spread, such as quarantine of outbreak areas) within a specif ied period (two months or six months, see Table 1). By including a “copayment” of the deductible, the insured farmers would have a more comprehensive coverage during catastrophic events,with the total costs being shared among the government, the private sector, and farmers.

    Table 1 Description of attributes and levels

    The “insurance premium” determines the annual amount that a farmer pays to the insurance provider for the production insured (price is set as the amount paid per ha insured).When the insurance is fairly priced, risk-averse producers should insure. There are a number of factors that aff ect the level of premium rates, which include, for example, the frequency of risks in a particular area, the type and number of risks covered, the sensitiveness of the insured crops, the number of farms insured, bonuses and subsidies, and other technicalities (Bielza Díaz-Caneja et al. 2009). Thus, in this context, since it is not possible to obtain real prices for the choice alternatives, we have considered as a starting point the crop insurance premium paid in the area of study. The premiums displayed in the choice cards (see Table 1) represent the f inal cost to the farmers, after the government applied a subsidy.1The motivation for including only the post-subsidized premium was the desire to follow the current procedures used in insurance products in Spain, and thus to avoid causing a respondent confusion and easiness during the CE.

    3.2 Construction of the Choice Set

    The experimental design was based on a B-effi cient design(Olsen and Meyerhoff 2016) with the restriction that high coverage choice alternatives must have higher prices than those that off er lower coverage–a requirement for actuarial fairness. The B-effi ciency criterion relies on preventing choice sets containing alternatives that may be strongly dominated. Olsen and Meyerhoff ( 2016) obtained the interesting result that choices from a B-effi cient design are more consistent than when using D-, C-, and S-effi ciency designs. We used the NGENE (ChoiceMetrics 2012) software and each farmer was presented with six choice cards to avoid respondent fatigue. Each choice card consisted of four alternatives(three insurance products and an option of no insurance).An example of a choice card is shown in Fig. 1. A ranking experiment using a best-worst approach was employed, but only the best ranks were used for the analysis as suggested by Caparrós et al. ( 2008), Scarpa et al. ( 2011), Varela et al.( 2014), and Agúndez et al. ( 2022), among others.

    3.3 Questionnaire Design and Sampling Strategy

    In addition to the described choice experiment, we also surveyed respondents’ experience with: (1) crop insurance products and their general satisfaction with insurance products available to them; (2) their risk perceptions regarding plant pests and disease outbreaks; and (3) their previous investment in biosecurity measures. A pilot version of the questionnaire was distributed among producers as well as agricultural academics, insurance experts, agricultural cooperative managers, and policy advisers. Modif ications were made following suggestions from the experts and farmers. In particular, the questionnaire was shortened to avoid respondent exhaustion and clarif ications were added to the text.

    Fig. 1 Example of a choice card

    Due to the lack of a dataset of active crop producers in the area, potential participants were identif ied through local agricultural cooperatives and agricultural groups. Agricultural organizations were contacted through email and invited to forward the questionnaire to associated members of their group to participate in the choice experiment. Because the study area is rural and the sample population was anticipated to be inexperienced with online questionnaires, data collection was complemented with face-to-face surveys over a period of three weeks. Main agricultural cooperatives and vegetable collection centers were identif ied and permission was requested to invite potential participants during their designated offi ce hours. Participants who still preferred to complete the questionnaire at a more convenient time were forwarded the online version.

    At the beginning of the data collection process, potential respondents were presented with a summary of the project.This document detailed the objectives of the work as well as provided background information regarding current insurance products and mandatory requirements during pest outbreaks. Participants were also given a consent form, outlining their agreement to take part in the study and emphasizing the voluntary and conf idential nature of the questionnaire.Stated preference methods have been subject to criticism,particularly regarding the validity of the results due to the hypothetical nature of the experiments. Hypothetical bias is thus an undeniable issue in CE, but empirical evidence does not render CEs unable to represent real-world preferences (Haghani et al. 2021a). We applied bias-mitigation methods (List and Gallet 2001; Murphy and Stevens 2004)2Studies have found that the magnitude of hypothetical bias is statistically less for willingness to pay (WTP) as compared to willingnessto-accept (WTA), for private compared to public goods, and that a choice-based method reduces the bias. Moreover, most farmers were expected to have experience with insurance products.to enhance behavioral realism in hypothetical choice data.An opt-out reminder (Ladenburg and Olsen 2014) is a useful approach to reduce the cheap talk, since it explicitly reminds respondents that they can choose the opt-out alternative, and it contributes to hypothetical bias mitigation (Haghani et al.2021b).

    3.4 Statistical Analysis

    Eliciting preferences through a choice experiment assumes that a respondent maximizes his utility through the choices over the alternatives presented (Train 2009). Random parameters logit (RPL), also known as the mixed logit model, is a commonly used model to analyze choice data because the model’s f lexibility permits it to represent a range of respondent behaviors. This model assumes that the unobserved utility of a crop insurance programjcan be split into two components: a deterministic one expressed by an indirect utility function,V, and a random error term,e.Vis a function of the attributes of the alternatives and a set of unknown parameters to be estimated, andecaptures unobservable factors that inf luence utility. Thus, the random utility gained by individualifrom choosing insurance programjin a particular choice tasktcan be written as:Uijt=Vijt+eijt. We assume that the indirect utility derived from a crop insurance program is a linear function of all the program’s attributes and of an alternative specif ic constant (ASC), which is coded as 1 when a program is presented and zero otherwise. A negative coeffi cient of the ASC represents farmers’ preferences for no insurance, that is, it is an initial welfare loss when the farmers purchase a nonspecif ied insurance. We also included two interaction terms between price and the coverage attributes. The interaction terms represent the imposed restriction in the choice design that higher coverage products are more costly than low coverage products.

    The specif ication of the indirect utility function becomesVijt=β′xijt, wherexijtis the matrix of attribute levels (ASC,basic coverage (BC), high coverage (HC), additional measured (addit), deductible (deduct), government co-payment within 6 months (copay6), government co-payment within 2 months (copay2), price, and the interaction variables of price with coverage), andβis the vector of coeffi cients(р,α1,α2,γ,δ,η1,,η2,Ψ,λ1,λ2).

    Because the design includes a constraint that premiums depend on coverage levels (more coverage implies higher premiums), the mean implicit prices for each attribute could be calculated as3If the price coeffi cient is distributed lognormally, and the coeffi -cients of nonprice attributes are normal, then the WTP is the ratio of a normal term to a lognormal term.:

    Nevertheless, as the WTP is an estimate of the ratio of two random variables, the WTP has a distribution of its own(Train 2009). There are several ways to compute the WTP,such as to consider the moments for estimation or to follow the Bayesian approach proposed by Greene et al. ( 2005).For the calculation of WTP for the diff erent attributes from the RPL estimates, we used the software developed by Hess( 2010), moving from the typical unconditional distribution(at sample population level) to a conditional distribution based on 10,000 simulated draws from the farmers participating in the study.

    4 Results

    The survey was completed by 181 farmers. Some observations were deleted due to respondents being outside the case study area, or not being crop producers at the time the questionnaire was released. This was probably due to the sampling procedure reaching farmers outside the scope of the study. The f inal dataset included 142 respondents. This is consistent with recent CE applications focusing on farmers/landowners in rural settings (Zandersen et al. 2021) and it is above the minimum sample required for our experimental design (Cranford and Mourato 2014).

    Most farmers (75%) had not purchased insurance in the past, and 67% claimed to have little knowledge of insurance products available to them. Nineteen percent of the respondents were dissatisf ied with current insurance programs off ered, and the main reasons were “main risks not covered,” and “compensation payments too low.” While crop insurance is voluntary in Spain, roughly half of the respondents claimed that crop insurance should be mandatory, and over 75% believe that insurance is a better risk management mechanism than ad hoc compensation payments. On average, our sample self-identif ied as risk-prone.Of the correspondents, 57% claimed to have suff ered important losses due to plant pest and disease outbreaks and 68%believed that they will experience substantial economic losses in the future. Almost 70% of the respondents claimed that they always or often make biosecurity control eff orts such as destroying infected crops, using pesticides, using certif ied seeds, and so on, and 60% thought that they should be partially or fully compensated for the costs of biosecurity controls; while 25% thought that they should be compensated in full and receive additional funds because their prevention and control eff orts would avoid costs to others.

    A number of models were estimated over respondent choices, including multinomial logit, willingness to pay in space, and latent class models. Both normal and lognormal forms of distribution were tested for the insurance attributes as well.4With the normal distribution, some individuals will have negative coeffi cients and others positive, and the lognormal distribution is useful when the coeffi cient is known to have the same sign for every person, such as the price coeffi cient that is known to be negative for everyone in a mode choice situation (Train 2009).The best statistical f it and most parsimonious model was found to be a RPL purely based on the functional form used in the experimental design, that is, with attributes,interaction terms between the price and coverage attributes,and a nonrandom ASC. The model assumes a normal distribution for all attributes except for the premium, which follows a lognormal distribution. The results in Table 2 include the values of the random parameters logit coeffi cients, their statistical signif icance, and the standard error. The McFadden pseudo R-squared for the RPL model was 0.316, that is,higher than the minimum value recommended in the literature (Christie et al. 2007).

    The estimated coeffi cient for the ASC was negative and signif icant, meaning that there are some unidentif ied variables that induce farmers to prefer to not purchase any of the off ered insurance products. These variables might include other types of insurance design attributes, but might also ref lect the existing reluctance to join insurance schemes,as previously mentioned. The positive coeffi cients for both coverage levels, basic and high, mean that respondents prefer a basic or a full coverage, instead of the medium coverage. This can be due to farmers perceiving that it is not worth insuring against recurrent pests and pathogens, which may be due to growers’ commonly adopting management strategies to address common pest and diseases, availableat cheaper costs, such as the use of pesticides (Santeramo and Ramsey 2017; Beckie et al. 2019). Higher coverage is the preferred option, as evidenced by a signif icantly higher positive coeffi cient. Requiring compliance with additional production measures to increase crop health decreases the preference for insurance. Similarly, the higher the deductible percentage, the lower the likelihood that farmers would take an insurance contract. Off ering government co-payments of the deductible amount during catastrophic outbreaks increases the demand for insurance, especially if the payment is promised in a shorter period. The demand for crop insurance decreases with the insurance premium, as expected by the Law of Demand (basically, that at a higher price consumer will demand a lower quantity of a good).The interaction of the coverage attribute with prices represents the restriction we imposed on the choice experiment design to represent the general condition that insurance products that off er coverage against more risks carry higher premiums. Therefore, the interaction terms are signif icant and negative, that is, an increase in the premium for low or high coverage decreases the demand. The nonstatistical signif icance of the standard deviation of these random parameters suggests that preferences of individuals are similar on these interacted attributes, namely, on how a change in price changes their preferences about the coverage.

    Table 2 Results of the random parameters logit model

    Economic interpretation of the results can be obtained from the implicit prices–the marginal rates of substitution between price and insurance attributes. These changes reveal how willing growers are to trade one insurance design attribute for another. The results are included in Table 3. We also included the standard deviation for the mean values and the conf idence intervals at 95% level.

    The negative WTP for the ASC represents farmers’ preferences for no insurance. Farmers are willing to pay over 51€/ha for a high coverage against potential catastrophic novel pests, and 43€/ha for a basic coverage that covers only climatic risks. Regarding the cost-sharing element, growers require a discount of 11€/ha if the insurance product requires compliance with additional biosecurity-related production measures, such as certif ication requirements. The implicit price for the deductible describes farmers’ preferences towards 1% changes in the deductible. Thus, for a 10%increase in the deductible, the implicit price is a deduction of 5.90€/ha. Lastly, if the government agrees to bear the deductible amount during catastrophic events, farmers are willing to pay 14.74€/ha more if the payment is promised within 6 months and 17.87€/ha if the payment is received within 2 months from the time of the claim.

    Because of the restriction in the design regarding the coverage and premiums, the total WTP for an insurance of certain coverage needs to account for the implicit price of the coverage amount as well as the eff ect of the interaction term. When the implicit price for the interaction term for high coverage is more negative than for basic coverage,this implies that while farmers are willing to pay more for high coverage products that protect them against novel plant pests and diseases, this result only holds for lower insurance premium amounts. The WTP for high and low coverage diff ers for low price levels, since once the price reaches approximately 50€/ha, the WTP for either coverage insurance drops to zero.

    Table 3 Implicit prices of insurance attributes

    5 Discussion

    In this study we explored preferences for comprehensive crop insurance products based on private-public partnerships that off er farmers the f lexibility to face common and novel pest and disease risks, while encouraging prevention eff orts,and we identif ied the scheme attributes that would increase the uptake of insurance. We developed a choice experiment to evaluate grower’s willingness to pay for diff erent crop insurance products in Spain. Thus, our analysis represents a contribution to the emerging literature on the use of CE data for crop insurance demand modelling.

    Insurance premiums and their subsidies are often key factors in determining the demand for insurance (Garrido and Zillbermann 2008; Bielza Diaz-Caneja et al. 2009).We found that Spanish farmers are not willing to pay substantially for a crop insurance on novel biological threats.This result is in line with the broad literature (Smith and Glauber 2012). As Hazell et al. ( 1986) mentioned, farmers are sometimes even unwilling to pay the full cost of all risk insurance or the actuarially fair premium rate. For example, Mercadé et al. ( 2009) found that if they estimated the WTP for vegetable insurance using levels similar to those currently in off er, the resulting willingness to pay is negative, which conf irms the low rate of insurance participation.The low WTP values found in this study could be a latent connection with previously negative experiences with insurance products, because the vast majority of our respondents were unaware of or unsatisf ied with policies currently off ered. Interestingly, while the statistical results show limited demand for crop insurance, the respondents agreed that insurance is a better mechanism than ad hoc catastrophic compensation; and roughly half of the producers stated that crop insurance should be made mandatory, presumably to force uptake in the face of the low demand. The respondents preferred insurance products with full coverage, including protection from novel pests and diseases. Thus, moving away from specif ic peril insurance to comprehensive coverage can provide the f lexibility that farmers require and thus may improve insurance penetration (European Commission 2018). Moreover, the WTP for a 10% increase in the deductible was ? 5.90 €/ha, lower than found in similar literature (Mercadé et al. 2009). While most insurance products off ered in Spain require a 30% deductible (Agroseguro 2015), it might be worth reevaluating this condition in preference to a lower threshold of uncovered damages to make insurance products more suitable to farmers (Mercadé et al. 2009).

    In considering the design of insurance schemes, we also investigated the potential of linking farmer eligibility to access ad hoc funds for the purchase of agricultural insurance. Linking government payments to the purchase of insurance through a co-payment in the eventuality of a catastrophic event can act as an additional incentive for uptake. We found that, when government catastrophic outbreak support is connected to insurance, the respondents are willing to pay up to 17.89 €/ha more for those policies. Other authors have also explored the boundaries of insurance and ad hoc compensation. For example, Liesivaara and Myyr?( 2017) found that in order for a crop insurance market to develop in Finland, the government should either pay disaster relief payments or provide insurance premium subsidies,but refrain from using both. We provide an alternative in which crop insurance could be a prerequisite for eligibility for participation in government programs such as disaster relief, thus separating the role of catastrophic assistance and risk management subsidization.

    We also explored the eff ects of requiring additional biosecurity-related production measures for insurance purchase,such as requiring traceability of the seeds and vegetables planted and health certif ication that would contribute to limit the spread and impacts of pests and diseases. Farmers require a decrease in insurance premium of 11 €/ha if biosecurity constraints are required. Previous literature already mentioned the co-benef its of crop insurance, such as Reyes et al. ( 2017), who claim that crop insurance can even be a climate change mitigation and adaptation strategy since it can provide farmers with the risk management tools to invest in more risky and higher value crops. For example, PCIC (the crop insurance program implemented in the Philippines) has dual objectives–enhancing access to credit, and managing risks from natural calamities, pests,and diseases (Reyes et al. 2017). It is important to note that from a biosecurity policy perspective, subsidized agricultural insurance can be also justif ied because insured farmers are more likely to report the incidence of infectious plants and diseases without delay because they will receive compensation for their losses (Goodwin and Vado 2007). The early reporting of outbreaks also provides governments and the private sector with information about the spread and abundance of diseases, which makes early and quick action possible. Recognizing the value of ancillary benef its adds signif icant value to crop insurance as a risk management tool for both farmers and governments (Santeramo and Ramsey 2017).

    6 Conclusion

    There is a consensus among insurance companies, governments, and farmers’ associations that crop insurance markets tailored to diff erent types of farms should exist and be promoted (European Commission 2018). Subsidized agricultural insurance can lead to higher penetration into the potential market of uninsured farmers, more accountability of risks and damages, and improved f inancial performance,as well as deliver additional biosecurity benef its (Reyes et al.2017). The main challenge for the Spanish subsidized system is to ensure its development within a changing policy environment, while simultaneously modulating and lessening ex post facto disaster assistance. Insurance products could be developed further to best serve the needs of farmers against novel threats. In particular, it seems that partially subsidizing national systems, expanding eligible risks covered for crops, developing more f lexible and simplif ied policies, and providing more information could go a long way to increase farmers’ participation in insurance schemes. Although the aim of this study was not to evaluate the supply and actuarial fairness of insurance policies, the article provides a foundation to stimulate further contributions that explore farmer’s preferences for diff erent risk management policies that limit the societal impacts of emerging plant pest and disease outbreaks. To this end, we studied the potential role of crop insurance that can promote ancillary benef its. Subsidized crop insurance can be used to encourage farmers to adopt appropriate biosecurity practices, thus helping reduce adverse environmental consequences of agriculture. Such practices can also promote a culture of agricultural health by encouraging detection of and early action against crop pests and diseases.

    Some f inal important remarks to consider are that once a government subsidizes the insurance program, the private sector has incentives to lobby for increased subsidies to enhance their revenues and returns (Smith and Glauber 2012). Any income transfer program that requires market interventions creates distortions in the markets, and crop insurance subsidies are no exception (Smith and Glauber 2012). Potential ancillary benef its also f low from subsidized insurance, which might justify the ineffi ciencies created.Regarding the eventual presence of hypothetical bias, most of the survey respondents selected the opt-out alternative presented in the choice cards, that is, the respondents show a clear preference for no insurance. This preference, consistent with previous works (List and Gallet 2001; Murphy et al. 2004), suggests that the eff ect of hypothetical bias in our WTP results is, as was expected, low in our case study.A shortcoming of the study was that the relatively short and simple CE questionnaire, needed to engage a hard-to-reach population of small farmers typical of the studied region, did not allow us to capture the complexity of attitudes towards risk and uncertainty as an important factor determining limited adoption of insurance. A further analysis of heterogeneity would require a new CE study specif ically designed for the exploration of the heterogeneity in farmer preferences.In addition, this research combines data collection methods. Although it is recommended to limit data collection to one method to avoid biases, due to the geography and demographics of the respondents and the absence of a recent census, a mixture of methods was used to reach more farmers. Lastly, we acknowledge that the monetary values that farmers place on accepting diff erent insurance conditions are specif ic to each case study. Thus, the results of this study need to be tested in other regions to verify the extent of their broader applicability.

    AcknowledgmentsWe would like to thank all the participants of this study–without their opinions and experiences this work would not have been possible. We would like to express our gratitude to the following agricultural associations for distributing the survey among their members: Cooperativas Agroalimentarias, AGACA–Asociación Galega de Cooperativas Agrarias, Sindicato Labrego, UPA–Unión de Peque?os Agricultores y Ganaderos, A Pementeira, Melisanto Sociedade Cooperativa, Horsal Sociedade Cooperativa, Postoiro Sociedade Cooperativa, and Patatas Ama. We would like to extend special thanks to Ramon Mato Sánchez, Javier Rodríguez Sánchez, Inés Amboage García, Higinio Mougán, Paula Kreisler Moreno, José Ramón Pedreira Dono, Oscar Antón Pérez García, Adolfo Leiva Quintela, Ganadería Fisteus y Bola?o SC, A Carpaceira de Campos SC, Pedro Martínez Escalona, and Santiago Ruiz Suso. Lastly, thanks to Dr Jon Pitchford,for proofreading the article, and Prof. Stephane Hess for developing the free software for the estimation of WTP using conditional parameter estimates from mixed logit models.

    Open AccessThis article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing,adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format,as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http:// creat iveco mmons.org/ licen ses/ by/4. 0/ .

    aaaaa片日本免费| 欧美日韩一级在线毛片| 1024香蕉在线观看| 熟女电影av网| 久久青草综合色| 欧美日韩福利视频一区二区| 露出奶头的视频| 国产野战对白在线观看| 超碰成人久久| 丰满人妻熟妇乱又伦精品不卡| 久久性视频一级片| 国产精品日韩av在线免费观看| 亚洲美女黄片视频| 欧美精品亚洲一区二区| 国产aⅴ精品一区二区三区波| 在线观看日韩欧美| 久久人妻福利社区极品人妻图片| 久久久国产欧美日韩av| 成年版毛片免费区| 夜夜躁狠狠躁天天躁| 美女 人体艺术 gogo| 久久精品国产亚洲av高清一级| 美女高潮到喷水免费观看| 成人国产一区最新在线观看| 欧美 亚洲 国产 日韩一| 国产高清videossex| 欧美乱妇无乱码| 国产精品九九99| 亚洲国产精品999在线| 一级a爱视频在线免费观看| 淫妇啪啪啪对白视频| 精品一区二区三区四区五区乱码| 51午夜福利影视在线观看| 午夜免费观看网址| 日韩免费av在线播放| 无限看片的www在线观看| 伦理电影免费视频| 中文字幕人妻熟女乱码| 性色av乱码一区二区三区2| 精品国产美女av久久久久小说| 亚洲国产欧美日韩在线播放| 国产熟女xx| 伦理电影免费视频| 国产精品美女特级片免费视频播放器 | 午夜视频精品福利| 两个人看的免费小视频| 18禁黄网站禁片午夜丰满| 狠狠狠狠99中文字幕| 亚洲成人国产一区在线观看| 自线自在国产av| 少妇熟女aⅴ在线视频| 久久国产精品人妻蜜桃| 非洲黑人性xxxx精品又粗又长| 国产成人精品久久二区二区91| 久久久久久久久久黄片| av天堂在线播放| 亚洲专区国产一区二区| 怎么达到女性高潮| 99久久综合精品五月天人人| 一区二区三区精品91| 亚洲精品中文字幕一二三四区| 免费高清视频大片| www日本黄色视频网| 亚洲av成人不卡在线观看播放网| 夜夜看夜夜爽夜夜摸| 又黄又爽又免费观看的视频| 搡老熟女国产l中国老女人| 怎么达到女性高潮| 制服人妻中文乱码| 成人亚洲精品av一区二区| 免费在线观看成人毛片| 亚洲成av人片免费观看| 国产精品久久视频播放| av视频在线观看入口| av在线天堂中文字幕| 在线天堂中文资源库| 国产一卡二卡三卡精品| 亚洲国产看品久久| 亚洲国产精品999在线| av天堂在线播放| 国产高清视频在线播放一区| 在线观看免费视频日本深夜| 在线十欧美十亚洲十日本专区| 男男h啪啪无遮挡| 国产成人av激情在线播放| 国产精品 欧美亚洲| 婷婷丁香在线五月| 老司机午夜十八禁免费视频| 男人操女人黄网站| 高清毛片免费观看视频网站| 一个人观看的视频www高清免费观看 | 国产黄a三级三级三级人| 国产亚洲欧美在线一区二区| 午夜福利一区二区在线看| 无遮挡黄片免费观看| 午夜影院日韩av| 成人国产一区最新在线观看| 在线观看www视频免费| av免费在线观看网站| 手机成人av网站| 欧美激情久久久久久爽电影| 久久精品亚洲精品国产色婷小说| 99久久99久久久精品蜜桃| 热re99久久国产66热| 成人精品一区二区免费| 怎么达到女性高潮| 午夜免费鲁丝| 亚洲人成网站高清观看| 精品久久久久久久久久久久久 | 亚洲,欧美精品.| 美女午夜性视频免费| 中文字幕人成人乱码亚洲影| 巨乳人妻的诱惑在线观看| 亚洲国产精品sss在线观看| 午夜免费成人在线视频| 成人国产一区最新在线观看| 久久久久久九九精品二区国产 | 精品国产超薄肉色丝袜足j| 在线观看66精品国产| 少妇熟女aⅴ在线视频| 欧美国产精品va在线观看不卡| 黑人操中国人逼视频| 国产成人精品久久二区二区免费| 日日夜夜操网爽| 国产精品野战在线观看| 免费一级毛片在线播放高清视频| 精品国内亚洲2022精品成人| 黑人欧美特级aaaaaa片| 九色国产91popny在线| 91老司机精品| 男女那种视频在线观看| 久久国产精品人妻蜜桃| 高潮久久久久久久久久久不卡| 一级毛片精品| 91大片在线观看| 欧美国产日韩亚洲一区| 国产激情久久老熟女| 中文字幕精品亚洲无线码一区 | 桃色一区二区三区在线观看| 午夜激情福利司机影院| 国产亚洲av嫩草精品影院| 99riav亚洲国产免费| 在线观看午夜福利视频| 99久久无色码亚洲精品果冻| 黄频高清免费视频| 一夜夜www| 叶爱在线成人免费视频播放| 久久久国产精品麻豆| videosex国产| 黄色视频不卡| 免费高清视频大片| 久久精品影院6| 国产91精品成人一区二区三区| 久久精品国产亚洲av香蕉五月| 一a级毛片在线观看| 亚洲国产精品999在线| av天堂在线播放| 亚洲电影在线观看av| 久久精品91蜜桃| 一边摸一边做爽爽视频免费| 亚洲色图av天堂| 国产乱人伦免费视频| 美女国产高潮福利片在线看| 美女国产高潮福利片在线看| 白带黄色成豆腐渣| 国产精品98久久久久久宅男小说| 婷婷精品国产亚洲av| 欧美精品啪啪一区二区三区| 女性被躁到高潮视频| 亚洲va日本ⅴa欧美va伊人久久| 国产免费男女视频| 搞女人的毛片| 国产亚洲精品一区二区www| 日日爽夜夜爽网站| 中文字幕久久专区| 啦啦啦观看免费观看视频高清| 夜夜躁狠狠躁天天躁| 国产精品电影一区二区三区| 看片在线看免费视频| 欧美日本视频| 香蕉久久夜色| av电影中文网址| 中文资源天堂在线| 91九色精品人成在线观看| 欧美日本视频| 超碰成人久久| 一级a爱视频在线免费观看| 亚洲精品国产区一区二| 韩国精品一区二区三区| 欧美在线黄色| 亚洲精品色激情综合| 国产一区二区三区在线臀色熟女| 日本免费a在线| 日韩高清综合在线| 午夜精品久久久久久毛片777| 国产成人一区二区三区免费视频网站| 国产视频内射| 亚洲avbb在线观看| 久久午夜综合久久蜜桃| 久久 成人 亚洲| 国产av一区二区精品久久| 日本精品一区二区三区蜜桃| 国产亚洲欧美在线一区二区| а√天堂www在线а√下载| 久久精品成人免费网站| 一边摸一边做爽爽视频免费| 国产成人欧美在线观看| 欧美国产日韩亚洲一区| 国产激情欧美一区二区| 99国产精品一区二区三区| 国产精品99久久99久久久不卡| 黄色 视频免费看| 美女高潮喷水抽搐中文字幕| 国产一区二区三区在线臀色熟女| 国内毛片毛片毛片毛片毛片| 成人午夜高清在线视频 | 亚洲中文日韩欧美视频| 天天一区二区日本电影三级| 美女国产高潮福利片在线看| 一级黄色大片毛片| 亚洲一区二区三区色噜噜| 国内少妇人妻偷人精品xxx网站 | 久99久视频精品免费| 国产成人一区二区三区免费视频网站| 女人被狂操c到高潮| 国产激情久久老熟女| 中文在线观看免费www的网站 | 精品久久久久久成人av| 午夜成年电影在线免费观看| 级片在线观看| 日日夜夜操网爽| 亚洲午夜理论影院| 免费在线观看视频国产中文字幕亚洲| 日韩精品中文字幕看吧| 在线观看66精品国产| 成人特级黄色片久久久久久久| 97碰自拍视频| 国产精品久久久av美女十八| 日本 av在线| 久久精品影院6| 男女之事视频高清在线观看| 日韩高清综合在线| 中文字幕精品亚洲无线码一区 | 黑人操中国人逼视频| 手机成人av网站| 欧美一区二区精品小视频在线| 国产在线观看jvid| 美女高潮喷水抽搐中文字幕| a级毛片a级免费在线| 亚洲aⅴ乱码一区二区在线播放 | 成人午夜高清在线视频 | 亚洲熟女毛片儿| 神马国产精品三级电影在线观看 | 日韩精品青青久久久久久| 黄片小视频在线播放| 亚洲性夜色夜夜综合| 又大又爽又粗| 午夜老司机福利片| 国产成人啪精品午夜网站| 久久国产亚洲av麻豆专区| 亚洲午夜精品一区,二区,三区| 丝袜在线中文字幕| 美女午夜性视频免费| 欧美激情极品国产一区二区三区| 最近最新中文字幕大全免费视频| 嫁个100分男人电影在线观看| 国产日本99.免费观看| 最新美女视频免费是黄的| av电影中文网址| 国产99白浆流出| 啦啦啦免费观看视频1| 欧美激情极品国产一区二区三区| 亚洲aⅴ乱码一区二区在线播放 | 1024视频免费在线观看| 午夜老司机福利片| 天堂影院成人在线观看| 女人爽到高潮嗷嗷叫在线视频| 久久香蕉精品热| 精品久久久久久,| 99在线人妻在线中文字幕| 亚洲国产精品成人综合色| 女警被强在线播放| 正在播放国产对白刺激| av电影中文网址| 悠悠久久av| 亚洲精品久久成人aⅴ小说| 精品久久久久久久毛片微露脸| 男人的好看免费观看在线视频 | aaaaa片日本免费| 观看免费一级毛片| 女性被躁到高潮视频| 午夜福利在线在线| 亚洲久久久国产精品| 国产精品久久久久久人妻精品电影| 99精品久久久久人妻精品| 在线播放国产精品三级| 女性被躁到高潮视频| 午夜影院日韩av| 露出奶头的视频| 中文字幕人妻熟女乱码| 一级毛片女人18水好多| 嫩草影视91久久| 欧美激情高清一区二区三区| 亚洲avbb在线观看| 国产黄片美女视频| 哪里可以看免费的av片| 女警被强在线播放| www.熟女人妻精品国产| 黄色成人免费大全| 免费高清视频大片| 欧美色视频一区免费| 黄色毛片三级朝国网站| 少妇粗大呻吟视频| videosex国产| 国产视频内射| 激情在线观看视频在线高清| 波多野结衣av一区二区av| 极品教师在线免费播放| 午夜老司机福利片| 免费一级毛片在线播放高清视频| 悠悠久久av| 黄色视频不卡| 在线观看免费午夜福利视频| 人妻丰满熟妇av一区二区三区| 一进一出抽搐gif免费好疼| 精品乱码久久久久久99久播| 国产av又大| 久久国产精品人妻蜜桃| 麻豆久久精品国产亚洲av| 美女高潮喷水抽搐中文字幕| 在线观看免费日韩欧美大片| 久久伊人香网站| 欧美日韩精品网址| 亚洲,欧美精品.| 91国产中文字幕| 精品国内亚洲2022精品成人| 好男人电影高清在线观看| 国产三级黄色录像| 午夜老司机福利片| 国产亚洲精品av在线| 91成人精品电影| 国产一区二区三区在线臀色熟女| 欧美中文日本在线观看视频| 欧美性长视频在线观看| 亚洲片人在线观看| 母亲3免费完整高清在线观看| 午夜久久久久精精品| 妹子高潮喷水视频| 亚洲精品美女久久久久99蜜臀| 免费在线观看黄色视频的| 真人做人爱边吃奶动态| 精品电影一区二区在线| 91av网站免费观看| 桃色一区二区三区在线观看| 免费无遮挡裸体视频| 亚洲无线在线观看| 欧洲精品卡2卡3卡4卡5卡区| 国内少妇人妻偷人精品xxx网站 | 曰老女人黄片| 欧美性猛交黑人性爽| 三级毛片av免费| 欧美日韩瑟瑟在线播放| 午夜福利一区二区在线看| 精品久久久久久久末码| 级片在线观看| 久久久久久免费高清国产稀缺| 国产高清激情床上av| 亚洲av第一区精品v没综合| 好男人在线观看高清免费视频 | 久久狼人影院| 亚洲av第一区精品v没综合| 国产区一区二久久| 窝窝影院91人妻| 日韩欧美国产一区二区入口| 99在线人妻在线中文字幕| 国产精品美女特级片免费视频播放器 | 成人一区二区视频在线观看| 国产午夜福利久久久久久| 亚洲激情在线av| 国产精品久久视频播放| 最新美女视频免费是黄的| 亚洲 欧美 日韩 在线 免费| 久热这里只有精品99| 一边摸一边抽搐一进一小说| 国产aⅴ精品一区二区三区波| 动漫黄色视频在线观看| 老鸭窝网址在线观看| 制服人妻中文乱码| 国产高清视频在线播放一区| 亚洲人成77777在线视频| 老司机午夜福利在线观看视频| 手机成人av网站| 黄片小视频在线播放| 操出白浆在线播放| 国产精品亚洲美女久久久| 一a级毛片在线观看| 黄片大片在线免费观看| 窝窝影院91人妻| 亚洲欧美日韩无卡精品| 99久久无色码亚洲精品果冻| 久久人妻av系列| www.自偷自拍.com| 99国产精品一区二区蜜桃av| 精品一区二区三区av网在线观看| 亚洲真实伦在线观看| 日韩欧美免费精品| 最新美女视频免费是黄的| 久久久久久九九精品二区国产 | 欧美日韩亚洲综合一区二区三区_| 一卡2卡三卡四卡精品乱码亚洲| 夜夜看夜夜爽夜夜摸| 国产精品日韩av在线免费观看| 亚洲成a人片在线一区二区| 色婷婷久久久亚洲欧美| 久久天堂一区二区三区四区| 两性夫妻黄色片| 男男h啪啪无遮挡| 波多野结衣av一区二区av| 一个人观看的视频www高清免费观看 | 人妻久久中文字幕网| 久久精品91蜜桃| 性色av乱码一区二区三区2| 精品久久久久久久久久久久久 | 一二三四社区在线视频社区8| 在线看三级毛片| 黄色成人免费大全| 亚洲精品粉嫩美女一区| 最新在线观看一区二区三区| 麻豆成人av在线观看| videosex国产| 一卡2卡三卡四卡精品乱码亚洲| 不卡一级毛片| 久久久精品欧美日韩精品| √禁漫天堂资源中文www| 日韩欧美 国产精品| 男女之事视频高清在线观看| 观看免费一级毛片| 人人妻人人澡欧美一区二区| 女人被狂操c到高潮| 午夜两性在线视频| 天天添夜夜摸| 久久久久精品国产欧美久久久| 国产爱豆传媒在线观看 | 日本免费a在线| 亚洲人成网站高清观看| 波多野结衣av一区二区av| 久久性视频一级片| 成人永久免费在线观看视频| 桃色一区二区三区在线观看| 日韩精品中文字幕看吧| 哪里可以看免费的av片| 特大巨黑吊av在线直播 | 国产精华一区二区三区| 香蕉久久夜色| 宅男免费午夜| 国产精品亚洲av一区麻豆| 久久久久久免费高清国产稀缺| 免费女性裸体啪啪无遮挡网站| 天堂影院成人在线观看| 婷婷精品国产亚洲av在线| 99riav亚洲国产免费| 91九色精品人成在线观看| 亚洲第一青青草原| 国产成人欧美在线观看| 不卡一级毛片| 大型av网站在线播放| 免费一级毛片在线播放高清视频| 在线观看一区二区三区| 精品熟女少妇八av免费久了| 亚洲午夜精品一区,二区,三区| 国产黄a三级三级三级人| 亚洲国产中文字幕在线视频| 成人国产一区最新在线观看| 丝袜人妻中文字幕| 一本大道久久a久久精品| 亚洲精品美女久久久久99蜜臀| 午夜福利成人在线免费观看| 日韩免费av在线播放| 一边摸一边抽搐一进一小说| 好看av亚洲va欧美ⅴa在| 波多野结衣高清作品| 国产精品久久电影中文字幕| 伊人久久大香线蕉亚洲五| 久久天躁狠狠躁夜夜2o2o| 看黄色毛片网站| 在线免费观看的www视频| 特大巨黑吊av在线直播 | 午夜精品久久久久久毛片777| 成年版毛片免费区| 俄罗斯特黄特色一大片| 脱女人内裤的视频| 色综合亚洲欧美另类图片| 欧美黄色淫秽网站| 日韩欧美 国产精品| 久久精品成人免费网站| 两性午夜刺激爽爽歪歪视频在线观看 | 午夜两性在线视频| 亚洲av第一区精品v没综合| 一区二区三区国产精品乱码| 他把我摸到了高潮在线观看| 可以免费在线观看a视频的电影网站| 久久久久久九九精品二区国产 | 大香蕉久久成人网| 曰老女人黄片| 国产精品av久久久久免费| 成人一区二区视频在线观看| 久久精品国产清高在天天线| 91麻豆av在线| 最好的美女福利视频网| 欧美日韩福利视频一区二区| 亚洲人成网站在线播放欧美日韩| 亚洲av熟女| 国产亚洲精品一区二区www| 欧美激情极品国产一区二区三区| 91大片在线观看| 日韩欧美一区视频在线观看| 亚洲成国产人片在线观看| 男人舔奶头视频| 别揉我奶头~嗯~啊~动态视频| 亚洲成人免费电影在线观看| 国产成人精品久久二区二区91| 91在线观看av| 色综合站精品国产| 免费在线观看日本一区| 国产精品免费一区二区三区在线| 午夜福利成人在线免费观看| 亚洲美女黄片视频| 99热6这里只有精品| 12—13女人毛片做爰片一| 午夜免费激情av| 国产精品一区二区精品视频观看| 久久精品国产亚洲av高清一级| 韩国av一区二区三区四区| 国产亚洲欧美在线一区二区| 人妻丰满熟妇av一区二区三区| 欧美激情 高清一区二区三区| 欧美国产日韩亚洲一区| 男人舔女人下体高潮全视频| 亚洲成a人片在线一区二区| 成人国产一区最新在线观看| 99精品久久久久人妻精品| 不卡一级毛片| 成人手机av| 亚洲国产高清在线一区二区三 | 国产精品 欧美亚洲| 亚洲国产看品久久| 精品久久蜜臀av无| 亚洲国产精品999在线| 十分钟在线观看高清视频www| 国产精品久久久久久亚洲av鲁大| 女警被强在线播放| 久久久久久九九精品二区国产 | 久久香蕉激情| 亚洲成人久久性| 欧美人与性动交α欧美精品济南到| 精品国产亚洲在线| 午夜福利视频1000在线观看| 久久国产精品影院| 18美女黄网站色大片免费观看| 国产精品一区二区精品视频观看| 免费人成视频x8x8入口观看| 久久久久国产精品人妻aⅴ院| 国内毛片毛片毛片毛片毛片| 女人爽到高潮嗷嗷叫在线视频| 俄罗斯特黄特色一大片| 搡老熟女国产l中国老女人| 极品教师在线免费播放| av电影中文网址| 免费观看人在逋| 超碰成人久久| 成人午夜高清在线视频 | 少妇裸体淫交视频免费看高清 | 久久这里只有精品19| 久久欧美精品欧美久久欧美| 国内精品久久久久久久电影| 日本五十路高清| 国产97色在线日韩免费| 久久人人精品亚洲av| 久久精品国产99精品国产亚洲性色| 天天躁狠狠躁夜夜躁狠狠躁| 久久久久国产一级毛片高清牌| 99re在线观看精品视频| 午夜久久久在线观看| 国产一卡二卡三卡精品| 天堂影院成人在线观看| 亚洲,欧美精品.| 欧美一级a爱片免费观看看 | 国产一区二区在线av高清观看| 伦理电影免费视频| 一区二区日韩欧美中文字幕| 日本三级黄在线观看| 国产一卡二卡三卡精品| 91老司机精品| 女生性感内裤真人,穿戴方法视频| 黄色毛片三级朝国网站| 淫秽高清视频在线观看| 国产成+人综合+亚洲专区| 亚洲七黄色美女视频| 国语自产精品视频在线第100页| 母亲3免费完整高清在线观看| 侵犯人妻中文字幕一二三四区| 在线观看午夜福利视频| 欧美日韩黄片免| 国产麻豆成人av免费视频| 亚洲真实伦在线观看| 成年女人毛片免费观看观看9| 一a级毛片在线观看| 中文字幕最新亚洲高清| 波多野结衣高清作品| 99国产精品99久久久久| 国内毛片毛片毛片毛片毛片| 亚洲国产精品合色在线| 中亚洲国语对白在线视频| 又紧又爽又黄一区二区| 给我免费播放毛片高清在线观看|