• <tr id="yyy80"></tr>
  • <sup id="yyy80"></sup>
  • <tfoot id="yyy80"><noscript id="yyy80"></noscript></tfoot>
  • 99热精品在线国产_美女午夜性视频免费_国产精品国产高清国产av_av欧美777_自拍偷自拍亚洲精品老妇_亚洲熟女精品中文字幕_www日本黄色视频网_国产精品野战在线观看 ?

    Performance Volatility and Wage Elasticity: An Examination of Listed Chinese A-share Enterprises*

    2009-07-05 14:39:37DonghuChenYongjinShenndLihuChen
    China Journal of Accounting Research 2009年2期

    Donghu Chen** , Yongjin Shennd Lihu Chen

    aResearch Institute of Accounting and Finance, Nanjing University Department of Accounting, School of Business, Nanjing University, China

    Performance Volatility and Wage Elasticity: An Examination of Listed Chinese A-share Enterprises*

    Donghua Chena,** , Yongjian Shenaand Lihua Chena

    aResearch Institute of Accounting and Finance, Nanjing University Department of Accounting, School of Business, Nanjing University, China

    The management of future financial risk on the part of managers and changes in firm finances are two of the fundamental reasons for upward and downward rigidity of wages.The proxy variable for firm financial risk is volatility, the past performance of which is among the principal indicators of wage rigidity. In firms whose current performance is on the upswing, the greater the volatility in past performance, the smaller the elasticity ratio and the more acute the upward rigidity; the more stable past performance, the larger the elasticity ratio and the more acute the upward elasticity. In firms in which current performance is declining, greater past performance volatility leads to a larger elasticity ratio and more acute downward rigidity, whereas more stable such performance leads to a smaller elasticity ratio and more acute downward rigidity.

    JEL classification: E24; G32

    Wage rigidity; Performance volatility; Financial risk

    1. Introduction

    Economic theory is often used to explain financial phenomena. We are interested in this study whether certain economic phenomena can be explained by financial theory. We explore the causes of microenterprise-level wage rigidity and attempt to explain it from the financial point of view. Chen, Shen and Zhou (2009) found that wages in non-listed companies exhibit downward rigidity (firm performance in a particular year shows a growth trend, but not wages), and also characteristics of upward rigidity (firm performance declines in a particular year, but wages remain unchanged). We too find that the wages of A-share listed companies in China exhibit both upward and downward rigidity. There is a significant body of research within the economics literature that explores downward wage rigidity,1The economics literature provides a multi-dimensional explanation for downward wage rigidity, primarily drawing on the institutional and economic theory perspectives. The former considers that it is due to such institutional factors as government wage regulation, legislative protection, trade unions and collective bargaining, (Franz et al., 2006; Agell and Bennmarker, 2002; Stiglitz, 2000). The economic theory perspective comprises contract theory (Fischer, 1977), implicit contract theory (Baily, 1974), the sabotage model of efficiency wage theory (Shapiro and Stiglitz, 1984), the gift exchange model (Akerlof, 1984), the adverse selection model (Weiss, 1990), the employee turnover model (Stiglitz, 1974), the fair wage-effort hypothesis (Akerlof and Yellen, 1990) and the insider-outsider hypothesis (Lindbeck and Snower, 1988).but not from the financial point of view. We have not found any published research that describes or explains upward wage rigidity. One reason may be that the existing research on wage rigidity in the labor economics field concentrates on the individual level. Hence it draws on the incentive point of view to investigate the impact of changes in individual wages on staffeffort. This makes it very dif ficult to observe the impact of wages on an enterprise’s cash flow and financial risk.The majority of this research focuses on an interpretation of downward wage rigidity. Our study, in contrast, addresses the enterprise level. It also draws on the cash flow perspective to investigate the impact of changes in wages on future financial risk. We focus on the relationship between changes in performance and wage movements to explain both upward and downward wage rigidity.

    Workers’ wages involve labor remuneration and incentives and are an important component of production costs. Although executive compensation is also part of an enterprise’s expenses, executive compensation primarily manifests itself as incentives.Therefore, the relationship between remuneration changes and performance sensitivity inevitable differs between workers and executives. Normally, the total remuneration of workers is greater than that of senior executives. Changes in workers’ remuneration have a bigger impact on cash flows and this may have a significant consequence onfuture financing or investments, similarly to cash dividends.2In terms of large cash outflows, we believe that changes in wage movements are very similar to dividends: first, because they lead to large changes in the amount of corporate cash available, which may affect future investments and financing and second, because dividends also exhibit rigid characteristics. The growth of enterprises with an increase in dividends is greater than that of enterprises with a decrease in dividends, and the extent of a dividend decrease is generally far greater than that of an increase (Skinner and Soltes, 2008). Lintner (1956), Benartzi et al. (1997), Howatt et al. (2009), Lu and Wang (1999), Li and Song (2007), Skinner and Soltes (2008), and Kormendi and Zarowin (1996) have all investigated changes in dividends. Research in China and other countries has concluded that changes in a company’s wages policy signal the market that its level of corporate risk has altered, and performance persistence and volatility can proxy for changes in corporate risk. The findings and methodology of previous research on changes in cash dividends serve as a valuable reference for our study on changes in wages.Current financial research is concerned with cash dividends and stock repurchases, and thus studies of cash expenditures on wages, particularly the reasons for wage rigidity are infrequent. We explain upward and downward wage rigidity from the accounting and financial points of view.

    This paper argues that senior managerial attempts to manage future risk are one of the root causes of wage rigidity. Fluctuations in performance, which are considered to be a proxy for corporate financial risk, are one of its indirect causes. The findings of this study are as follows. Among businesses experiencing improved performance, the probability of future financial risk is greater if their past reported earnings has fluctuated widely. To reduce possible future risk, managers may decide to reduce workers’ wages: the greater the fluctuation in performance in previous years, the greater the decline in wages, the smaller the wage elasticity coefficient and the stronger is the upward rigidity. On the other hand, if reported earnings have been more stable in previous years, future financial risks are less likely. In this case, managers may choose to raise employee wages: the more stable the firm’s performance, the greater the extent of this wage increase is likely to be, the larger the wage elasticity coefficient and the stronger the upward flexibility. Among businesses experiencing a decline in performance, the probability that managers will reduce wages is greater the more widely that performance has fluctuated in previous years. In addition, the wage elasticity coefficient is greater and the downward flexibility stronger. The more stable business performance has been in previous years, the greater the extent of the increase in wages, the smaller the wage elasticity coefficient and the stronger the downward rigidity.

    This paper explains wage rigidity at the enterprise level from the financial point of view. Its main contributions are: (1) to expand the body of research about the effect of a company’s finances on changes in employee wages, and (2) to enrich the literature on the impact of performance volatility and the significance of employee wage levels in enterprises from the financial accounting perspective.

    The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Part 2 presents a literature review; Part 3 discusses the institutional context, theoretical analysis and research assumptions; Part 4 covers the samples, variables and variable definitions; Part 5 presents the descriptive statistical analysis; Part 6 covers the empirical analysis and Part 7 the robustness tests; and, finally, Part 8 discusses the study’s findings.

    2. Literature Review

    Drawing on the literature about interpretations of dividend changes, we employ performance volatility as a proxy for future business risk in order to explain the causes of wage rigidity from the financial point of view. This study links together aspects of the literature on wage rigidity, the impact of performance volatility and the significance of wages in enterprises.

    2.1. Explanation of Wage Rigidity Provided by Economic Theory

    Economic theory argues that wage rigidity differs by firm type. Downward wage rigidity has been explained at the institutional and economic theory levels. The institutional level considers the effects of wage legislation, trade unions and a collective consultation system. If a firm is subject to mandatory wage legislation, strong trade union power and robust collective bargaining mechanisms, then wages will display characteristics of downward rigidity. Only after a negotiated agreement with employees may wages be reduced (Holden, 1994). Economic theory includes contract theory (Fischer, 1977), implicit contract theory (Baily, 1974), the sabotage model of ef ficiency wage theory (Shapiro and Stiglitz, 1984), the gift exchange model (Akerlof, 1984), the adverse selection model (Weiss, 1990), the employee turnover model (Stiglitz, 1974), the fair wage-effort hypothesis (Akerlof and Yellen, 1990) and the insider-outsider hypothesis (Lindbeck and Snower, 1988).

    Neither the institutional nor economic theory literature explains wage rigidity on the basis of an enterprise’s financial situation. Nor is financial situation or financial risk management used to explain downward such rigidity. Although we adopt an enterpriselevel definition of wage rigidity,3The definition of rigidity in economic theory is based on the individual.we believe that the definition and interpretation of such rigidity stems from the actual business situation of enterprises. Our approach differs from previous economic theory literature because our definition of wage rigidity covers both upward and downward rigidity. This two-pronged approach and our explanation of the two types of wage rigidity from the financial point of view are the main contributions of this study.

    2.2. Information Content of Performance Volatility

    A company’s performance is to a large extent influenced by the risks that result from its operating and financial activities. Performance volatility is attributable to the inherent uncertainty of fluctuations in revenue and operating costs. It also results from the financial costs of the interest on debt financing, changes in workers’ wages, and so on. Many studies show that performance volatility conveys information about a company’s level of risk to the market (Howatt et al., 2009) and that higher degrees ofvolatility have a negative effect on firm value (Allayannis and Weston, 2003; Barnes, 2001). Other studies are concerned about the impact of performance volatility on forecasts of future performance (Minton et al., 1999; Dichev and Tang, 2009; Petrovic et al., 2009; Brennan and Hughes, 1991; Schipper, 1991). Financial analysts and institutional investors are generally reluctant to make predictions about the performance of enterprises with higher levels of volatility because doing so may increase their forecast error and result in negative surprises (Badrinath et al., 1989). Enterprises that exhibit extreme performance volatility may reverse faster (Freeman, Ohlson and Penman, 1982), while high volatility may be due to the inclusion of temporary items, the sustainability of which is unlikely. Performance volatility may also have an impact on a company’s future financing costs (Trueman and Titman, 1988), as it signals a higher likelihood of failure.

    Another line of research has examined the impact of cash flow volatility on firm performance. For example, Minton and Schrand (1999) reported that cash flow volatility is positively correlated with average levels of capital expenditure, research and advertising costs, and significantly and negatively correlated with the cost of external financing. Allayannis and Weston (2003) reported that cash flow volatility has a significantly negative correlation with firm value. Moreover, the negative impact on firm value from fluctuations in accounting profits is of greater statistical and economic significance.These findings are entrenched in the financial and accounting literature (Petrovic et al., 2009).

    As performance volatility conveys information to the market about firm value, future performance and future financing costs, we are interested in determining whether management is aware of the inherent informational value of earnings volatility and quality and that it subsequently takes action to control risks.

    3. Institutional Background: Theoretical Analysis and Hypotheses

    Since the time of the socialist transformation of production in China in the mid-1950s, the wages in state-owned enterprises have been subject to planned control, with graded salaries being the norm. This has resulted in a fairly low degree of production efficiency in state-owned enterprises. To promote initiative at both the firm and employee levels, the Chinese government began in the 1980s to issue a series of macro-control measures on the distribution of national income, such as linking pay to performance and instituting flexible pay plans, thereby changing the original wage system pattern. After nearly two decades of reform, both urban and rural incomes have increased, and individuals have realized significant improvements in their quality of life. At the same time, however, the income gap has widened over the years (Lin, 2007) and now exceeds reasonable limits (Chen, 2007). To prevent income polarization among employees and to ensure that the principle of equity is met, towards the end of the 1900s the State implemented macro-control measures about wage allocation, includinglabor market and wage guidelines and minimum wage regulations. These measures have been primarily administrative in nature and lack rigid enforcement,4The government has both economic and political goals for wage and employment regulations. However, it retains stricter control over the number of employees than their wages, which may ultimately lead to excess employment in state-owned enterprises (Zeng and Chen, 2006).and no mechanism is yet in place to monitor their implementation or verify their results5Dong Keyong, director of the School of Public Administration at China Renmin University, holds the view that wages are like weather forecasts, which work as reference frames. Under market economy conditions, wages, or the price of labor, should be determined on the basis of the supply of labor and the demand of employers. Government wage guidelines work as macro-level guidance and reference, but should not be relied upon to increase wages (Yang, 2008).(Yang, 2008).

    To ensure continued improvement in living standards and to overcome defects and irregularities in the wage distribution system within enterprises, the central and local governments now require companies to establish a mechanism for the normal growth of wages of full-time employees. The 52nd administrative paper from the bureau of the People’s Government of Shandong Province (2007) states that all enterprises should ensure appropriate growth in wages and that a reasonable reduction in wages is allowed only if there is a decline in profits and a democratic process is followed. The government also regulates the wages of corporate executives, ruling that they cannot claim a wage increase if the average wages of their employees have experienced annual increases. This macro-level wage control may contribute to the downward rigidity of wages.

    Labor unions play a key role in the decision-making process of firms in many Western countries with regard to wage changes. By 2000 China promulgated ‘the Interim Measures on collective wage negotiations,’ and these have had some positive effects (Zhou, 2008; Guan, 2008). Because of status inequality, power imbalance and information asymmetry between employees and employers, employees often do not know how, or dare not negotiate with their employers, thus making the negotiation system meaningless (Zhou, 2008). The government has failed to enforce the wage guidelines it has issued, so that executives usually play the leading role in wage decisions and ultimately they have the freedom to allocate higher wages to themselves6For more detailed information, please refer to Li (2006). Managerial compensation and wages are far higher than the average wage level in China Ping An and other listed companies in the insurance and banking industries, a good example of the corporate right to freely allocate higher wages to executives.(Zeng and Chen, 2006; Li, 2006).

    As the agents of shareholders, executive managers will likely consider the company’s future financial risk when it deliberates about wage changes. This is due in part to firm value being affected by financial risk (Allayannis and Weston, 2003; Barnes, 2001). Financial risk includes fluctuations in foreign exchange rates, interest rates and product prices. Moreover, because of the imperfection of capital markets, the corporate risks related to agency costs, transaction costs and the costs of external financing are important factors in determining a company’s future financial condition. The management of such risks may be one way of improving firm value and benefiting shareholders (Bartram, 2000). In addition, increased volatility in a company’s performance in previous yearsadds to the unpredictability of its future performance, thus increasing the possibility of future financial risks. Fixed costs such as wages, dividends, and interest may reduce firm liquidity.

    Either explanation increases financial distress, which can propel the company into a vicious circle: if its past performance fluctuated significantly, this indicates the uncertainty of its future performance (cash flows), which might indicate the possibility that its liquidity will be insuf ficient to meet the aforementioned fixed costs. Hence, we can expect a decline in the company’s earning ability or solvency and a negative impact on its future investments (Minton and Schrand, 1999). If there is any doubt about a company’s ability to fulfill its payment obligations in full and on time, its transaction costs increase significantly. The costs resulting from financial distress or insufficient liquidity are determined by the degree or likelihood of decreased liquidity (Bartram, 2000).

    The fluctuation of firm performance may be the best signal of firm risk (Howatt et al., 2009). Research has shown that the more volatile its previous performance, the harder it is to predict its future performance accurately (Minton et al., 2002), the quicker the change in its mean reversal (Freeman, Ohlson and Penman, 1982), and the more likely its expected earnings will be negative (Badrinath et al., 1989). These factors may be accompanied by an increase in future financing costs (Minton and Schrand, 1999) and the possibility of financial distress. By observing fluctuations in performance, management may be able to measure the direct or indirect costs arising from financial distress or poor liquidity. These costs include the visible costs related to clients, suppliers, employees and creditors, as well as such recessive costs as direct contract costs and the indirect costs resulting from the transfer of employees and executives to competitors in response to financial distress (Bartram, 2000). Executives may seek to pre-empt these potential risks by engaging in risk management promptly. Although risk management cannot lower the direct and indirect costs of financial distress, it can reduce the likelihood of that distress and of liquidity shortfalls (Bartram, 2000).

    Increasing the firm’s cash reserves is an important objective of executive risk management. Firms require significant reserves of cash for such outlays as loan interest, cash dividends and wages. The interest on loans affords little flexibility, and cash dividends are decided by general shareholders meetings. However, the cash paid to employees is under managerial control, particularly in China, where labor unions are weak and collective wage negotiation is merely a formality (Zhou, 2008).

    Our goal in this paper is to use the financial perspective to explain why firm wages exhibit rigid characteristics. We are particularly interested in the following questions. Why do the wages in certain firms decline instead of increasing and why do they exhibit upward rigidity rather than upward flexibility when annual performance is on the upswing? Why do the wages in some firms increase rather than decline, and exhibit downward rigidity rather than downward flexibility when annual performance is on the decline? One reason for such wage rigidity may be the executive-level management of potential financial risks in the face of performance fluctuation.

    How should a firm’s past performance fluctuation be viewed when investigating wage rigidity? We agree that prior performance fluctuation contains information about a company’s level of risk (Minton et al., 1999; Dichev and Tang, 2009; Petrovic et al., 2009; Brennan and Hughes, 1991; Schipper, 1991). The more volatile a firm’s performance has been in the past, the less stable and predictable its future performance is likely to be. Analysts and investors cannot predict future performance on the basis of the company’s historical fluctuation or changes in current performance. It is the contention of this paper that to a large extent, the more volatile a company’s historical performance, the greater the likelihood that it needs to manage financial risks.

    Management needs to consider whether and how to change workers’ wages in the face of either an improvement or deterioration in firm performance. Wage changes differ from changes in managerial salaries because they involve significantly larger absolute amounts of money. This in turn may affect future corporate financing, investments and sustainability, as well as future labor costs and productivity of the workforce. Thus, wage decisions involve a trade-offbetween costs and benefits.

    Labor costs and the level of effort expended by the workforce are not affected by fluctuations in performance, but rather performance volatility affects the costs of financial distress. Relative to a stable company, the financial distress costs of a volatile company are larger. These costs include those that arise from managerial risks and from failing to take measures to reduce potential future financial risks. A sense of fairness is deeply rooted in Chinese culture, and workers’ perceptions of fairness are an important determinant of the level of effort they exert. The perception of fairness has a positive effect on workers’ level of effort and productivity and on corporate profits. If wages are reduced and workers feel unfairly treated, then they are less likely to work hard, which will impact negatively on the corporation. If management ignores this the net effect may be that financial distress costs become much larger than the costs of adjusting the current wage level. Therefore, management is more likely to actively manage risk. The cost of increasing wages (or the benefit of decreasing them) would thus be larger, which reduces the likelihood of increasing wages when the corporation performs better (upward rigidity), but increases the likelihood of doing so when performance declines (downward elasticity). The situation is asymmetrical.

    In enterprises in which performance has improved in the current year, but where performance has fluctuated widely in previous years, management is still likely to reduce wages to manage future financial risk. The greater the fluctuation, the greater the likelihood of such a reduction. If the improved performance is expected to last, then the lower the degree of elasticity, the stronger the upward rigidity. If a company’s past performance was relatively stable, then the likelihood of future financial risk is low, and management may raise workers’ wages to motivate them to work harder.7In addition to encouraging workers to work harder, government policy establish a normal wage increase mechanism may be another reason that companies increase wages.The more stable the company’s former performance, the larger the extent of the workers’ pay riseand the stronger the upward wage elasticity.

    Based on the foregoing discussion, we propose the following hypothesis.

    H1: In corporations whose performance has improved in the current year, the coefficient of wage elasticity is negatively correlated with former performance volatility.

    In corporations in which performance has deteriorated in the current year, and where the fluctuation in performance in former years has been large, management will tend to reduce workers’ wages to manage future financial risk. The greater the fluctuation, the greater the likelihood of such a reduction. If the deterioration in performance does not ease, then the larger the coefficient of wage elasticity, the stronger the downward elasticity.

    If a corporation exhibited relatively stable former performance, the low degree of fluctuation would signal to the market that the company has a low likelihood of future financial risk. If the company’s performance remains stable, even though it has deteriorated in the current year, management may still raise employees’ wages. The more stable the former performance and the larger the extent of improvement in the current year’s performance, the smaller the coefficient of wage elasticity and the stronger the downward wage rigidity. This discussion leads us to posit our second hypothesis.

    H2: In corporations whose performance deteriorated in the current year, the coefficient of wage elasticity is positively correlated with former performance volatility.

    4. Sample, Data and Definition of the Variables

    4.1. Sample

    Our research sample comprises companies listed as A-shares on the Shenzhen and Shanghai Stock Exchanges. Companies included have been listed since 1999, they pay annual wages ranging from 8,000 to 200,000 Yuan, and they have been in continuous existence for at least five years.8We required the companies in our sample to have existed for five or more years to ensure that we could compute increased wages and performance. Companies with data missing for a certain year were eliminated. Companies that delisted before 2007 were included, as long as they met the five-year survival requirement, which reduces the problem of survival bias.After eliminating companies in the finance industry and those with missing data, 7,347 observations of 933 companies are detailed in Table 1.

    Table 1. Sample DistributionPanel A: Sample Distribution by Length of Existence

    Panel B: Sample Distribution by Industry and Year

    Panel A of Table 1 displays the distribution of the sample companies by their period of existence. Panel B of Table 1 displays the sample distribution by industry and year.

    4.2. Data

    Our research data were obtained from the WIND and CCER databases. Data on the number of workers at the end of each year from 2002 to 2007 were collected manually from the websites of the Shenzhen and Shanghai Stock Exchanges. Market data for all provinces from 2001 to 2005 were obtained from the ‘Market Index of China’ (Fan, Wang and Zhu, 2007). The market data for 2006 and 2007 are assumed to be the same as for 2005.

    4.3. Definition of the Variables

    The names and definitions of the dependent variables, main independent variables and control variables used in this research are displayed in Table 2.

    Table 2. Variable Names, Codes and Definitions

    We use per capita cash flow, which includes basic wages, bonuses and allowances, as a substitute for wages. Bonuses may vary depending on current performance, but may not adjust to changes in that performance in a timely fashion, a problem we address in our robustness tests.

    We define the coefficient of wage elasticity as the ratio of the current year’s wage increase rate and current year’s performance increase rate (PW/PP). We claim that the wage is flexible if this variable is positive. The larger is this variable, the greater the elasticity of the wage and the greater the positive relativity between wages and performance. The wage is considered rigid if this variable is negative.11Refer to the definition of downward rigidity in the labor economics field, which states that workers’ wages may increase even when company performance deteriorates. We define upward wage rigidity as a decrease in wages even when company performance improves. According to this definition, if the coefficient of wage elasticity is negative, then wages appear to be rigid; if this coefficient is positive, then wages appear to be elastic.The smaller is the variable, the more rigid the wage and the larger the negative relativity between wages and performance. Similar to Chen, Shen and Zhou (2009), we differentiate between upward and downward elasticity and upward and downward rigidity.

    With reference to the research carried out by Howatt et al. (2009), Jayaraman (2008), Dichev et al. (2009) and Petrovic et al. (2009), we use the standard deviation of the performance in the last three years of period T as our proxy index of performance volatility. If an observation was missing data for the last three years of period T, then it was eliminated from the regression. In addition, to determine the influence of average performance on the coefficient of wage elasticity and to ensure the robustness of our conclusions, we also regressed CV and variance as the proxy variables of performance fluctuation in our robustness tests, in which we also analyzed ROE and different performance indexes, including ROA and OROA.12Although cash can be viewed as a performance index, we focus on accounting performance. Numerous accounting studies have demonstrated that accounting pro fit is more re flective of companies’ true performance, for example Dechow (1994), Dechow, Kothari and Watts (1998), and Ball and Shivakumar (2006). The research carried out by Allayannis and Weston (2003) also showed that companies’ cash flow fluctuations had no obvious in fluence on firm value, whereas fluctuations in accounting pro fit were remarkably negatively correlated with that value.Following Petrovic et al. (2009), we also included operating profit in our research, mainly because it does not include non-operating profit, thus helping to alleviate the influence of earnings management on performance fluctuation.

    To control the direction of performance fluctuations, we set continued performance improvement and deterioration dummy variables. We then cross-multiplied the continued performance improvement dummy variable (CI) and continued performance deterioration dummy variable (CD) by the continued performance fluctuation variable.

    We also controlled for earnings quality, initially using the contribution of operating profit to total profit (QPt-1) in period T-1. In the robustness test, we then employed the average proportion of operating profit in total profit for periods T-4 to T-1. We used this index to measure earnings quality because operating profit does not contain such temporal influences as non-operating income/expenses that would reduce the continuity of performance (Dichev et al., 2009).

    If the change13We conducted correlation analysis of the rate of wage change and the rate of change in the number of employees, and found them to be significantly negatively correlated at the 0.01 level. Hence, we controlled for the change in the number of employees when we analyzed the effect of performance volatility on the wage elasticity coefficient.in the number of workers in the current term (PNEt) and the wage level in the last term (LWt-1) are abnormally high or low, then current wages and current performance may change inversely. Thus we also controlled for this possibility. The existence of wage rigidity may result from companies’ self-adjustment according to their financial status and may arise from government intervention in companies’ marketoriented decisions. Thus, we controlled for the degree of marketization (MI) in the location in which the company operates. This index reflects the macro-environmental conditions in which companies make their market-oriented decisions, and includes such sub-indexes as the relationship between market and government, and the level of development in the input market. Because financing costs differ by company type (Petrovic et al., 2009), we controlled for such firm-level characteristics as industry, scale and debt ratio. To investigate whether the performance fluctuations of companies in good (non-ST companies) and bad operating conditions (ST companies) have different effects on wage policy, we retained the latter in our sample,14The asset-liability ratio of individual companies is negative because the sample is partially comprised of ST enterprises.but controlled for them by adding an ST dummy variable. As workers’ wages constitute a substantial financial outlay for a company, we controlled for other substantial outlays such as capital investments, based on cash dividend research (Kormendi and Zarowin, 1996), to analyze whether the latter influence companies’ wage policies. In addition, as the prevailing macro-economic conditions may have a significant influence on firm performance (Klein and Marquardt, 2006) and both labor and firm decisions (Shapiro and Stiglitz, 1984), we also included a macro-economic index, composed of GDP, the unemployment rate, of the district in which a company is located.

    5. Descriptive Statistics

    5.1. Descriptive Statistics of Main Variables

    Table 3 provides descriptive information on the sample.

    Table 3. Descriptive Statistics15The total sample is 7,347 firm-years and the sample from 1999 to 2002 is included because of the need to compute the performance variance of the last three years. The sample is 6,414 from 2002 to 2007. The actual sample is 4,966 firm-years in the regression for computing the firm volatility.

    Table 3 also provides the distribution of the main variables. The median of wage (W) and wage growth (PW) are significantly lower than the mean, which indicates that the distribution of wages and wage growth is uneven. Although the number of enterprises with high levels of wages or wage growth is small, the wages and wage growth of these few enterprises are relatively large, which is basically consistent with the wage distribution of non-listed companies reported in previous research (Chen, Shen and Zhou, 2009). Performance and performance volatility are distributed more evenly and are similar to the median and mean. The median (QP 96.79) and mean (QP 88.28) of earnings quality are fairly evenly distributed. According to the coefficient of elasticity, the medians of ELA_ROA and ELA_OROA are 0.09 and 0.08, respectively, which indicates that the wage elasticity sample is larger than the wage rigidity sample.

    Due to the dependent variable for wage elasticity being calculated from the ratio of the wage growth rate (PW) and the growth rate of the total return on assets (PROA), there are more outliers in the following multiple regression analysis, and thus the Winsorization process is adopted.

    5.2. Distribution of Firm Characteristics

    Table 4 provides descriptive statistics by year for the sample, which is divided into four categories based on firm characteristics.

    Table 4. Distribution of Sample Characteristics by Year16We also describe the sample by industry, areas (market) and property of the firms, but we do not find any obvious rule.

    Table 4 shows that between 1999 and 2007, the proportion of the sample exhibiting upward elasticity increased year on year from 8.93% to 54.76% and that the proportion exhibiting downward elasticity decreased from 45.24% to 9.02%. The ratio of upward and downward elasticity samples increased from 54.17% in 1999 to 63.78% in 2007.The proportion of the sample exhibiting downward rigidity over this period increased from 6.21% to 24.02%, whereas the proportion exhibiting upward rigidity declined. From the perspective of wage changes, the number of enterprises that increased wages (exhibiting upward elasticity and downward rigidity) increased year on year, from 15.14% in 1999 to 78.78% in 2007.

    5.3. Sub-Portfolio Analysis of Business Performance Improvement and Deterioration

    We divided 4,966 observations of the business performance improvement and decline samples into 10 portfolios in accordance with the standard deviation of performance. Table 5 provides the median of wage elasticity, wage characteristics and elasticity coefficient of each portfolio.

    Table 5.Panel A: Distribution of Wage Characteristics of Different Performance Volatility Portfolios of Companies with Improved Performance

    In Panel A of Table 5, in accordance with the standard deviation of performance, the sample is divided into 10 combinations. The proportion of observations in the first (upward elasticity) and second quadrants (upward rigidity) declines as performance volatility increases. The distribution of the number of enterprises is consistent with our expectations. According to the median of each portfolio’s standard deviation of performance, wage elasticity is gradually reduced from 1.02 to 0.32, whereas the standard deviation of performance in the upward elasticity sample increases with volatility. Wage elasticity increases from -0.68 to -0.21, whereas, in line with our expectations, the wage elasticity of the upward rigidity sample increases with volatility.

    Table 5.Panel B: Distribution of Wage Characteristics of Different Performance Volatility Portfolios of Companies with Deteriorating Performance

    Panel B of Table 5 shows that among firms with deteriorating performance, higher levels of performance volatility lead to the ratio of the two types of firms exhibiting a weak increasing trend. The ratio of the smallest volatility portfolio is 0.37 and that of the largest is 0.68, which, to a certain extent, shows that the percentage of firms exhibiting downward elasticity gradually increases with an increase in performance volatility.This outcome is in line with our expectations. The median of wage elasticity for each portfolio as well as the median of downward elasticity for the firms changed little with an increase in performance volatility. However, the median of downward rigidity for the firms increased gradually, from -1.10 to -0.48 with such an increase. This indicates that, contrary to our expectations, performance declined by 1%, the median wage of Portfolio one increased by 1.1% and that of portfolio ten by only 0.48%.

    Table 5 indicates that the wage elasticity of the upward elasticity and downward rigidity samples exhibits significantly decreasing or increasing trends with increased performance volatility. Wages in these two types of businesses have increased, which suggests that, relative to their counterparts that have decreased wages, the managers of these firms are more concerned about past performance volatility.

    5.4. Time-Series Characteristics of Wage Elasticity

    In order to investigate whether wage elasticity is self-relevant, we analyze the timeseries characteristics of wage elasticity and examine the following regression model.

    We conduct separate regressions of the two types of wage elasticity coefficients calculated by two types of variables (ROA and OROA) and find no correlation between any of the coefficients in periods t and t+1. The ? in the two regressions are -0.0001 and 0.00001, respectively, which do not pass the statistical significance test and are thus of no economic significance. We therefore infer that there is no continuity of elasticity; rather, managers adjust wages largely based on possible future changes in financial risk.

    6. Empirical Tests

    6.1. Univariate Tests

    To explain why wages exhibit upward and downward rigidity, we carried out mean and median tests of performance volatility and earnings quality respectively, for firms undergoing performance improvement and decline by using wages as a single-factor explanatory variable (see Table 6).

    Table 6.Panel A: Results of Mean and Median Tests of Performance Volatility in Enterprises with Improved Performance

    Panel A of Table 6 shows that the mean and median of the standard deviation of the return on assets (VROA) are 4.38 and 2.53, respectively, in the upward elasticity sample, which are both higher than those in the upward rigidity sample. After excluding the effects of nonrecurring gains and loss, the standard deviation of the operating return on assets (VOROA) exhibits the same result. Both the mean and median of VOROA in the upward elasticity sample are significantly higher than those in the upward rigidity sample at the 0.01 level.

    Table 6.Panel B: Results of Mean and Median Tests of Performance Volatility in Enterprises with Deteriorating Performance

    In line with our expectations, the mean and median of VROA (VOROA) are 2.67 (2.41) and 1.69 (1.68), respectively, in the downward elasticity sample, which are both lower, but insignificantly so, than those in the downward elasticity sample: 2.81 (2.47) and 1.75 (1.71).

    6.2. Multiple Regression Tests

    Considering that outliers will affect our research conclusions, we winsorized the top and bottom 1% of the outliers of the wage elasticity coefficient (ELA), performance volatility and earnings quality. To gain a more comprehensive understanding of how the other variables affect the relationship between performance volatility and the ELA, we conducted separate OLS multiple regression tests for H1 and H2 by building the following multiple regression model.

    6.2.1. Tests of H1

    To test H1, we ran a multiple regression for the samples with an increase in ROA, with the results reported in Table 7.

    Table 7.Panel A: OLS Multiple Regression for Samples with an Increase in ROA

    Regression (1) in panel A of Table 7 provides evidence to show that without controlling the other variables, VROA and ELA_ROA are significantly negatively correlated at the 0.01 level, which is consistent with our expectations. After controlling the other related variables, the results of regression (2) remain consistent with our expectations, but with higher explanatory power, increasing from 0.006 to 0.035. The significantly negative correlation of VROA and ELA_ROA at the 0.01 level suggests that the higher the volatile performance, the more that wages will be reduced relative to that performance and, as a result, the lower the wage elasticity coefficient. This regression result also indicates that managers carried out corresponding risk management to address the large degree of performance volatility. Although the current performance of their firms had improved, because of the large degree of performance volatility in previous years, the managers still restricted the amount of cash paid to and on behalf of employees, and hence wages exhibited upward rigidity. In firms whose performance had remained stable over the past few years and whose financial situation was healthy, in contrast, it was possible for managers to increase the wages of their employees. As their current performance had also improved, wages exhibited upward elasticity. This finding is not only consistent with risk management theory, but also supports H1. The coefficient of interactive options (CI×VROA) is 0.20, which is significantly positive at the 0.05 level, indicating that the more that performance continues to improve, the greater the growth rate and the more upwardly flexible are wages.

    Given that nonrecurring gains and losses may be due to wage changes, we carried out further regression analysis on the wage elasticity coefficient and performance volatility.This was calculated on the basis of operating return on assets (OROA) excluding the effect of nonrecurring gains and losses (see Panel B, Table 7).

    Table 7.Panel B: OLS Multiple Regression for Samples in Which OROA Had Increased

    Regression (1) in panel B of Table 7 provides evidence to show that without controlling the other variables, VOROA and ELA_ROA are significantly negatively correlated, which is consistent with our expectations. After controlling the other related variables, the coefficient of VOROA in regression (2) is -0.05, which is consistent in sign with our expectations, but not significant.

    The following conclusions can be drawn from Table 7. Regardless of whether a firm’s current performance had improved, the more its performance had fluctuated in previous years, the greater the possibility that it would face financial risks in future, and hence the greater the possibility that wages would be cut to reduce the probability of future financial risk and a shortfall in liquidity. As a result, wages exhibit upward rigidity.The more volatile is firms’ performance, the lower the wage elasticity coefficient and the stronger the upward wage rigidity. In companies whose performance had realized improvements in the current year and had been stable in previous years, the probability of future financial risk was smaller. Thus, their managers may have decided to increase staffwages to comply with government macro-control measures and to further their own economic interests. Salaries are therefore seen to manifest upward elasticity. The more stable performance had been in previous years, the higher the wage elasticity coefficient and the stronger the upward wage elasticity.

    6.2.2. Tests of H2

    To test H2, we ran a multiple regression for the samples in which ROA had decreased, with the results presented in Table 8.

    Regression (1) in panel A of Table 8 provides evidence to show that VROA and ELA_ROA are significantly positively correlated at the 0.01 level, which to a certain extent supports H2. After controlling the other related variables, the significance level of the VROA coefficient remained the same (whereas the T-value changed from 3.36 to 3.10) and the goodness of fit reached 0.03, which means that VROA’s power to explain the wage elasticity coefficient is partly replaced by the other variables. Although the performance of these firms declined in the current year, the more stable was their performance in previous years, the fewer financial risks they were likely to face in future, and the more likely that they would increase wages. Wages in these firms thus exhibited downward rigidity. In those companies in which performance had both deteriorated in the current year and fluctuated in previous years, wages were likely to be reduced and exhibited downward elasticity. We also carried out further regression analysis after excluding the effect of nonrecurring gains and losses (see Panel B of Table 8).

    Table 8.Panel A: OLS Multiple Regression for Samples in which ROA had Decreased

    Regression (2) in panel B of Table 8 provides evidence to show that VOROA and ELA_ROA are significantly positively correlated at the 0.01 level, which to a certain extent supports H2. After controlling the other related variables, the significance level of the VROA coefficient changed from 0.01 to 0.05.

    Table 8 indicates that despite a current decline in performance, if (a) a company’s performance had exhibited stability in recent years, (b) the financial situation is good and (c) the likelihood of future financial risk is small, then managers may still raise staffwages to comply with government macro-control measure and to further their own economic interests. Therefore, salaries in such firms manifest downward rigidity. The more stable the performance in previous years, the lower the wage elasticity coefficient and the stronger the downward wage rigidity. In those companies in which performance both decreased in the current year and fluctuated in previous years, however, managers are likely to cut staffwages to reduce the probability of future financial risk. Downward elasticity thus manifests itself in the wages of these firms. The more volatile is the performance in previous years, the higher the wage elasticity coefficient and the stronger the downward wage elasticity.

    Table 8.Panel B: OLS Multiple Regression for Samples in which OROA had Decreased

    7. Robustness Checks

    To further test the stability of our results, we conducted the following robustness checks.

    7.1. Replacement of Key Indicators

    We used the standard deviation of the return on total assets (ROA) and the operating return on total assets (OROA) as an alternative indicator of performance volatility. In this robustness check, we used the profit growth rates when calculating wage flexibility and the wage elasticity coefficients. The regression results are presented in Table 9. The use of variance and the coefficient of performance variation as alternative indicators of performance volatility did not change the regression results substantially.

    Table 9.Panel A: OLS Multiple Regression of the Sample with Increased Profits

    Table 9.Panel B: OLS Multiple Regression of Sample with Decreased Profits

    It can be seen from Table 9 that the regression results on the wage elasticity coefficient that we obtained by employing the profit growth rate are similar to those obtained by using the return on total assets.

    7.2. Adjustment of Nominal Wage Growth Rate to Real Wage Growth Rate

    In this paper, we consider only the growth rate of nominal wages, which equals the wage difference between two adjacent periods divided by the wage level of the former period. By taking into account the impact of the CPI in different years on wage adjustments, we adjusted the nominal wage in accordance with the following formula.

    Using the adjusted real wage growth rate to redefine the rigidity and elasticity coefficients, we obtained the regression results presented in Table 10.

    Table 10.Panel A: OLS Multiple Regression of Sample with Increased ROA

    Table 10.Panel B: OLS Multiple Regression of Sample with Decreased ROA

    The regression results remained basically unchanged when price changes were taken into account.

    7.3. Adjustment of the Wage Elasticity coefficient Definition

    We define the wage elasticity coefficient as the ratio of the wage growth rate in period t divided by the performance growth rate in period t-1. Taking into account that in reality wage adjustments may take place after performance changes, we adjusted our definition of the wage elasticity coefficient according to the following formula.

    The results of the regression run after redefining the wage elasticity coefficient are presented in Table 11.

    Table 11.Panel A: OLS Multiple Regression of Sample with Increased ROA

    Table 11.Panel B: OLS Multiple Regression of Sample with Decreased ROA

    It can be seen from Table 11 that when we lag the wage growth rate by one period, the sign of the one independent variable regression is contrary to our expectations. Although the sign of the multiple independent variable regression on performance fluctuation is in accordance with our expectations, it does not pass the significance test.

    7.4. Regression on State-Owned and Private Enterprises

    To determine whether the nature of firms’ property rights has an impact on the relationship between performance fluctuation and the wage elasticity coefficient, we employed state-owned and private enterprises as our regression samples. The results of the former sample are basically consistent with those of the full sample. In the private enterprise sample, however, the direction of the performance fluctuation impact on the wage elasticity coefficient is in line with our expectations, but does not pass the significance test.

    7.5. Regression with the Compensation and Number of Executives, Directors and Supervisors Excluded

    When we removed the compensation paid to executives, directors and supervisors from that paid to employees and their numbers from the total number of employees, the regression results changed little and are basically in accordance with our expectations.

    7.6. Performance Volatility over Four Years, Including Current Year Performance

    Given that senior management takes into account the current year’s performance as well as the performance volatility of previous years, we also took it into account in our calculation of performance volatility. Thus, when calculating the indicators of performance fluctuation, we used performance data for the current year as well as those for the past three years. The regression results using this revised calculation were still in line with our expectations and support our hypotheses.

    7.7. Stability Test of Heteroscedasticity

    To overcome the possible impact of heteroscedasticity and ensure the stability of inference, we used robust OLS estimates. The regression results were largely unaffected by heteroscedasticity and were in accordance with our expectations.

    7.8. Excluding Abnormal Samples

    We removed the outliers of the elasticity coefficient, performance, volatility and earnings quality from the top and bottom 1%, and the results remained basically unchanged.

    8. Research Conclusions and Limitations

    Taking A-share listed companies in China from 1999 to 2007 as our research sample, this article analyzes the causes of wage rigidity from the financial perspective. We demonstrate that firms whose current performance has improved, but whose performance in previous years has fluctuated, face a greater likelihood of future financial risks, and thus their management may reduce employees’ wages to avoid those risks.The greater the fluctuation in a firm’s former performance, the greater the decrease in employees’ wages, the smaller the wage elasticity coefficient and the stronger the upward rigidity. If the firm’s performance in previous years was less volatile, then it is less likely to face financial risks in future and management is more likely to increase staffwages both in the interests of the company and to manage potential risk. The more stable the former performance, the greater the increase in wages, the larger the wage elasticity coefficient and the stronger the upward elasticity. In firms whose performance is deteriorating, the greater the fluctuation in its former performance, the more it decreases employee wages, the larger the wage elasticity coefficient and the stronger the downward elasticity. The more stable that former performance, the more wages are increased, the smaller the wage elasticity coefficient and the stronger the downward rigidity.

    A limitation of this paper lies in its definition of wage elasticity. Such elasticity is defined as the current wage growth rate divided by the current performance growth rate.There are two issues of concern regarding this definition. First, if the elasticity coefficient is less than zero, then it is considered that wages exhibit rigidities. The definition exaggerates the downward flexibility and upward rigidity samples to some extent because a drop in the average wage does not necessarily mean a decrease in the wage level, but may also result from a change in employee numbers or a firm’s internal structure. Even if we had controlled the variable for the change in employee numbers, this substantial deviation could not have been avoided. Second, our definition involves the assumption that wage adjustment is a short-term concept. In practice, however, wages (except for bonuses) may be adjusted every two or more years. We adjusted the definition of the wage elasticity coefficient by employing the ratio of the wage growth rate over two years divided by the performance growth rate over two years, but the results were contrary to our expectations. Furthermore, a company’s operating leverage, cost structure, and ability to bargain with clients and suppliers may also affect the flexibility of wage adjustments. However, given the limited data available, we were unable to control such variables, which may have had an impact on the reliability of our conclusions.

    Agell, J., Bennmarker, H., 2002. Wage policy and endogenous wage rigidity: A representative view from the inside. CESifo Working Paper, CESifo.

    Akerlof, G. A, 1984. Gift exchange and ef ficiency-wage theory: Four views. American Economic Review 74(2), 79-83.

    Akerlof, G. A., Yellen, J., 1990. The fair wage-effort hypothesis and unemployment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 105, 255-83.

    Allayannis, G., Weston, J. P., 2003. Earnings volatility, cash flow volatility, and firm value. Working Paper, University of Virginia and Management Rice University.

    Badrinath, S. G., Gay, G. D., Kale, J. D., 1989. Patterns of institutional investment, prudence and the‘managerial safety’ net hypothesis. Journal of Risk and Insurance 56, 605-629.

    Baily, M. N., 1974. Wages and employment under uncertain demand. Review of Economic Studies 41, 37-50.

    Ball, R., Shivakumar, L., 2006. The role of accruals in asymmetrically timely gain and loss recognition. Journal of Accounting Research 44 (2), 207-42.

    Barnes, R., 2001. Earnings volatility and market valuation: An empirical investigation. LBS Accounting Subject Area Working Paper, London Business School.

    Bartram, S. M., 2000. Corporate risk management as a lever for shareholder value creation. Financial Markets, Institutions & Instruments 9 (5), 279-324.

    Benartzi, S., Michaely, R., Thaler, R., 1997. Do changes in dividends signal the future or the past? Journal of Finance, 52 (3), 1007-1034.

    Brennan, M., Hughes, P., 1991. Stock prices and the supply of information. Journal of Finance 46 (5), 1665-1691.

    Chen, D., Shen, Y., Zhou, Y., 2009. Wage rigidity and firm performance: Empirical research based on nonlisted companies. Working Paper, Nanjing University. (In Chinese)

    Chen, L., 2007. June 25. The income gap and consumer demand. China Economic Times, quoted in Chinese Economic Papers Library: http://thesis.cei.gov.cn. (In Chinese)

    Dechow, P., 1994. Accounting earnings and cash flows as measures of firm performance: The role of accounting accruals. Journal of Accounting and Economics 18 (1), 3-42.

    Dechow, P., Kothari, S. P., Watts, R., 1998. The relation between earnings and cash flows. Journal of Accounting and Economics 25 (2), 133-168.

    Dichev, I., Tang, V. W., 2009. Earnings volatility and earnings predictability. Journal of Accounting and Economics 47, 160-181.

    Fan, G., Wang, X., Zhu, H., 2007. NERI INDEX of marketization of China’s Provinces 2006 Report. Economic Science Press, Beijing. (In Chinese)

    Fischer, S., 1977. Long-term contracts, rational expectations, and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 85 (1), 191-206.

    Franz, W., Pfeiffer, F., 2006. Reasons for wage rigidity in Germany. Labor 20 (2), 255-284.

    Freeman, R. N., Ohlson, J. A., Penman, S. H., 1982. Book rate-of-return and prediction of earnings changes: An empirical investigation. Journal of Accounting Research 20 (2), 639-653.

    Guan, M., 2008. Research on collective wage consultation system. Journal of China Institute of Industrial Relations 4, 5-9. (In Chinese)

    Holden, S., 1994. Wage bargaining and nominal rigidities. European Economic Review 38, 1021-1039.

    Howatt, B., Zuber, R. A., Gandar, J. M., Lamb, R. P., 2009. Dividends, earnings volatility and information. Applied Financial Economics 19 (7), 551-562.

    Jayaraman, S., 2008. Earnings volatility, cash flow volatility, and informed trading. Journal of Accounting Research 46 (4), 809-851.

    Klein, A., Marquardt, C. A., 2006. Fundamentals of accounting losses. The Accounting Review 81 (1), 179-206.

    Kormendi, R., Zarowin, P., 1996. Dividend policy and permanence of earnings. Review of Accounting Studies 1, 141-160.

    Research Team on Income Distribution in State-owned Enterprises, 2006. Research and views on income distribution in some state-owned enterprises in the City of Beijing. Journal of Beijing Federation of Trade Unions Cadre College 2, 6-12. (In Chinese)

    Li, Z., Song, Y., 2007. Dividend policy, earning continuity and signal display. Nan Kai Business Review 10 (1), 70-80. (In Chinese)

    Lin, Y., 2007. The crux of the too large income gap lays in the reform. Economic Frontier 10, 4-7. (In Chinese).

    Lindbeck, A., Snower, J. D., 1988. The insider-outsider theory of employment and unemployment. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

    Lintner, J., 1956. Distribution of incomes of corporations among dividends, retained earnings and taxes. American Economic Review 46 (2), 97-113.

    Lu, C., Wang, K., 1999. Dividend policy of listed companies: Empirical analysis. Economic Research 12, 31-39. (In Chinese)

    Minton, B., Schrand, C., 1999. The impact of cash flow volatility on discretionary investment and the costs of debt and equity financing. Journal of Financial Economics 54, 423-460.

    Minton, B., Schrand, C., Walther, B., 2002. The role of volatility in forecasting. Review of Accounting Studies 7, 195-215.

    Petrovic, N., Manson, S., Coakley, J., 2009. Does volatility improve UK earnings forecasts? Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 36 (9-10), 1148-1179.

    Schipper, K., 1991. Commentary on analysts’ forecasts. Accounting Horizons 5, 105-121.

    Shapiro, C., Stiglitz, J., 1984. Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device. American Economic Review 74, 433-444.

    Skinner, D. G, Soltes, E., 2008. What do dividends tell us about earnings quality? Review of Accounting Studies, Forthcoming.

    Stiglitz, J., 1974. Wage determination and unemployment in L.D.C.s: The labor turnover model. Quarterly Journal of Economics 88, 194-227.

    Stiglitz, J., 2000. Economics (Vol. 1). China Renmin University Press, Beijing.

    Trueman, B., Titman, S., 1988. An explanation for accounting income smoothing. Journal of Accounting Research 26, 127-139.

    Weiss, A., 1990. Efficiency wages: Models of unemployment, layoffs and wage dispersion. Princeton University Press, Princeton.

    Yang, S., 2008. China’s collective bargaining system: A dif ficult journey. Chinese and Foreign Corporate Culture 10, 15-17. (In Chinese)

    Yang, Z., 2008, June 23. Wage guidelines: Hard to increase wages. China News Weekly. (In Chinese)

    Zeng, Q., Chen, X., 2006. State-controlled, over-employment and labor costs. Economic Research 5, 74-86. (In Chinese)

    Zhou, Z., 2008. The problems in employees’ earning rights and the strategy of labor unions. Journal of China Institute of Industrial Relations 1, 62-65. (In Chinese)

    * This paper is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation (grant no. 70602011) and the National Social Science Foundation (grant no. 08CJY009). We also appreciate the support we have

    from the IAPHD Project of Nanjing University and the discussion with the participants at the second young accounting scholar seminar at Peking University in 2009. We give special thanks to Xiongsheng Yang, Bin Ke, Feng Liu, Peter Chen, Yuan Ding, Chaomi Zhang, Ran Zhang, Yongqiang Ma, Xiang Li, Xin Yu and Wei Lv for their valuable comments and advice. We thank the anonymous referees for their constructive suggestions.

    ** Corresponding author. Donghua Chen: E-mail address: dhchen@nju.edu.cn. Correspondence address: Research Institute of Accounting and Finance, Nanjing University, Nanjing, China, 210093. Yongjian Shen: E-mail address: yjshen@smail.nju.edu.cn. Lihua Chen: E-mail address: njuclh@nju.edu.cn.

    国产在线男女| 日本成人三级电影网站| 波多野结衣巨乳人妻| 久久久欧美国产精品| 小蜜桃在线观看免费完整版高清| 12—13女人毛片做爰片一| 男女做爰动态图高潮gif福利片| 欧美日韩乱码在线| 99国产精品一区二区蜜桃av| a级毛片免费高清观看在线播放| 天堂√8在线中文| 国产高清视频在线观看网站| 禁无遮挡网站| 成人综合一区亚洲| 亚洲电影在线观看av| 国产精品av视频在线免费观看| 听说在线观看完整版免费高清| 简卡轻食公司| 看黄色毛片网站| 日韩欧美 国产精品| av免费在线看不卡| 亚洲va在线va天堂va国产| 如何舔出高潮| 国语自产精品视频在线第100页| 成人三级黄色视频| 极品教师在线视频| 日韩,欧美,国产一区二区三区 | 91狼人影院| 大型黄色视频在线免费观看| 国产一区二区激情短视频| 久久国内精品自在自线图片| 十八禁国产超污无遮挡网站| av在线蜜桃| 九九久久精品国产亚洲av麻豆| 岛国在线免费视频观看| 色av中文字幕| 老熟妇乱子伦视频在线观看| 国产精品久久久久久精品电影| 我要搜黄色片| 欧美另类亚洲清纯唯美| 久久鲁丝午夜福利片| 国产午夜精品久久久久久一区二区三区 | 插阴视频在线观看视频| 亚洲天堂国产精品一区在线| 欧美区成人在线视频| 久久99热这里只有精品18| 99久久无色码亚洲精品果冻| 蜜桃久久精品国产亚洲av| 一个人看视频在线观看www免费| 亚洲精品一区av在线观看| 露出奶头的视频| 热99re8久久精品国产| 99久久精品一区二区三区| 免费在线观看影片大全网站| 露出奶头的视频| 秋霞在线观看毛片| 成人高潮视频无遮挡免费网站| 欧美日韩在线观看h| 日韩欧美免费精品| 高清毛片免费看| 免费av不卡在线播放| 男女做爰动态图高潮gif福利片| 毛片一级片免费看久久久久| 国产色爽女视频免费观看| 全区人妻精品视频| 国产av不卡久久| 国产淫片久久久久久久久| 久久久精品大字幕| 亚洲精品亚洲一区二区| 日韩成人av中文字幕在线观看 | 日韩制服骚丝袜av| 国产精华一区二区三区| 麻豆一二三区av精品| 国产乱人视频| 一级毛片电影观看 | 变态另类丝袜制服| 久久人人爽人人片av| 亚洲国产日韩欧美精品在线观看| 日本与韩国留学比较| 综合色丁香网| 亚洲精品乱码久久久v下载方式| 成年版毛片免费区| 亚洲av免费在线观看| 国内精品宾馆在线| 久久久久久久久中文| av中文乱码字幕在线| 欧美性猛交黑人性爽| 久久人人爽人人片av| 色5月婷婷丁香| 国产精品无大码| 91在线精品国自产拍蜜月| 女的被弄到高潮叫床怎么办| 日本成人三级电影网站| 欧美一区二区国产精品久久精品| 久久精品国产99精品国产亚洲性色| 搡老熟女国产l中国老女人| 亚洲成人精品中文字幕电影| 中国美女看黄片| 又爽又黄a免费视频| 在线观看免费视频日本深夜| 色吧在线观看| 日本欧美国产在线视频| 在线播放无遮挡| 亚洲欧美日韩无卡精品| 亚洲精品久久国产高清桃花| 啦啦啦韩国在线观看视频| 久久热精品热| 最近中文字幕高清免费大全6| 欧美极品一区二区三区四区| 亚洲欧美精品自产自拍| 舔av片在线| 欧美色欧美亚洲另类二区| 熟妇人妻久久中文字幕3abv| 热99在线观看视频| 亚洲国产精品成人久久小说 | 嫩草影视91久久| 亚洲最大成人av| 女人被狂操c到高潮| 国产精品国产高清国产av| 男女做爰动态图高潮gif福利片| 一本久久中文字幕| 亚洲国产日韩欧美精品在线观看| 国产蜜桃级精品一区二区三区| 免费观看的影片在线观看| 精品国内亚洲2022精品成人| 91av网一区二区| 性插视频无遮挡在线免费观看| 十八禁国产超污无遮挡网站| 日本与韩国留学比较| 欧美激情在线99| 国产在视频线在精品| 国产成人精品久久久久久| 久久久久久国产a免费观看| 国产日本99.免费观看| 色5月婷婷丁香| eeuss影院久久| videossex国产| 国产在线精品亚洲第一网站| av在线观看视频网站免费| 久久6这里有精品| 级片在线观看| 人人妻人人澡欧美一区二区| 日韩高清综合在线| 在线播放无遮挡| 一a级毛片在线观看| 男人的好看免费观看在线视频| 国产精品电影一区二区三区| 日韩中字成人| 久久久国产成人免费| 精品国内亚洲2022精品成人| 搡老岳熟女国产| 亚洲婷婷狠狠爱综合网| 国产伦精品一区二区三区四那| 欧美日本亚洲视频在线播放| 国产亚洲av嫩草精品影院| 午夜免费男女啪啪视频观看 | 久久久久久久亚洲中文字幕| 精品人妻视频免费看| 亚洲高清免费不卡视频| 亚洲成av人片在线播放无| 久久久久久久久久黄片| 欧美3d第一页| 精品一区二区三区视频在线观看免费| or卡值多少钱| 国产色爽女视频免费观看| 此物有八面人人有两片| 一区二区三区免费毛片| 97超碰精品成人国产| 少妇被粗大猛烈的视频| 国产真实乱freesex| 色5月婷婷丁香| 国产精品久久久久久精品电影| 国产精品一区www在线观看| 国产精品99久久久久久久久| 天堂动漫精品| 亚洲久久久久久中文字幕| 国产一级毛片七仙女欲春2| 乱人视频在线观看| 国产色爽女视频免费观看| 欧美又色又爽又黄视频| 国产精品久久视频播放| 91在线观看av| 亚洲av美国av| 校园春色视频在线观看| 日韩av不卡免费在线播放| 欧美激情在线99| 黄色欧美视频在线观看| 看非洲黑人一级黄片| 久久午夜亚洲精品久久| 三级经典国产精品| 中国国产av一级| 亚洲精品乱码久久久v下载方式| 国产免费一级a男人的天堂| 俄罗斯特黄特色一大片| 成人美女网站在线观看视频| 看非洲黑人一级黄片| 麻豆国产av国片精品| 欧美绝顶高潮抽搐喷水| 久久精品综合一区二区三区| 天堂影院成人在线观看| 婷婷色综合大香蕉| 狂野欧美白嫩少妇大欣赏| 欧美不卡视频在线免费观看| or卡值多少钱| 免费观看精品视频网站| 国产成人91sexporn| 别揉我奶头~嗯~啊~动态视频| 国产精品99久久久久久久久| 少妇的逼好多水| 亚洲av不卡在线观看| 不卡一级毛片| 亚洲五月天丁香| 小蜜桃在线观看免费完整版高清| 亚洲av免费在线观看| 女人被狂操c到高潮| 国产极品精品免费视频能看的| av在线天堂中文字幕| 国产大屁股一区二区在线视频| av天堂在线播放| 久久久久国内视频| 亚洲国产日韩欧美精品在线观看| 亚洲一级一片aⅴ在线观看| 亚洲成a人片在线一区二区| 国产高清不卡午夜福利| 日日干狠狠操夜夜爽| 联通29元200g的流量卡| 国产精品久久久久久精品电影| 麻豆精品久久久久久蜜桃| 国产视频一区二区在线看| 成人漫画全彩无遮挡| 最近最新中文字幕大全电影3| 国产av在哪里看| 一本久久中文字幕| 一个人看的www免费观看视频| 亚洲国产欧美人成| 精品久久久久久久久久免费视频| 久久精品国产亚洲av香蕉五月| 欧美xxxx性猛交bbbb| 人人妻人人澡人人爽人人夜夜 | 亚洲人成网站高清观看| 婷婷六月久久综合丁香| 国产单亲对白刺激| 男人舔奶头视频| 一区二区三区免费毛片| 国产毛片a区久久久久| 有码 亚洲区| 欧美高清性xxxxhd video| 国产乱人视频| 99在线视频只有这里精品首页| 久久久久国产网址| 偷拍熟女少妇极品色| 精品久久久噜噜| 国产一区二区三区av在线 | 一级毛片aaaaaa免费看小| 成人国产麻豆网| aaaaa片日本免费| 你懂的网址亚洲精品在线观看 | 97在线视频观看| 日本三级黄在线观看| 最好的美女福利视频网| 成人av在线播放网站| 亚洲专区国产一区二区| 成人午夜高清在线视频| 国产精品亚洲美女久久久| 亚洲精品色激情综合| 午夜福利成人在线免费观看| 日韩欧美精品v在线| 午夜爱爱视频在线播放| 人妻夜夜爽99麻豆av| 少妇猛男粗大的猛烈进出视频 | 免费看a级黄色片| 在现免费观看毛片| 欧美日韩综合久久久久久| 偷拍熟女少妇极品色| 联通29元200g的流量卡| 精品午夜福利在线看| 免费黄网站久久成人精品| 国产精品福利在线免费观看| 亚洲人与动物交配视频| 免费在线观看影片大全网站| 给我免费播放毛片高清在线观看| av福利片在线观看| 亚洲aⅴ乱码一区二区在线播放| 免费av观看视频| 久久久久久久久久黄片| 国产aⅴ精品一区二区三区波| 国产 一区精品| 久99久视频精品免费| 亚洲人成网站在线播放欧美日韩| av卡一久久| 中国美白少妇内射xxxbb| 哪里可以看免费的av片| 亚洲人成网站高清观看| 久久久久久久久久黄片| 国产久久久一区二区三区| 2021天堂中文幕一二区在线观| 最近在线观看免费完整版| 国产毛片a区久久久久| 99九九线精品视频在线观看视频| 国产亚洲精品综合一区在线观看| 91久久精品国产一区二区三区| 女人被狂操c到高潮| 中文资源天堂在线| av黄色大香蕉| 国产极品精品免费视频能看的| 国产一区二区三区在线臀色熟女| 内地一区二区视频在线| 不卡一级毛片| 淫秽高清视频在线观看| 成人亚洲精品av一区二区| 国产视频一区二区在线看| 国产一区亚洲一区在线观看| 日韩 亚洲 欧美在线| 国内精品一区二区在线观看| 美女黄网站色视频| 美女 人体艺术 gogo| 日韩,欧美,国产一区二区三区 | 国内精品美女久久久久久| 中国国产av一级| 国产乱人偷精品视频| 日本免费一区二区三区高清不卡| 亚洲av第一区精品v没综合| 老女人水多毛片| 悠悠久久av| 日本a在线网址| 日韩在线高清观看一区二区三区| 中国国产av一级| 成人精品一区二区免费| 国产精品日韩av在线免费观看| 99热这里只有是精品50| 亚洲18禁久久av| 老师上课跳d突然被开到最大视频| 男女下面进入的视频免费午夜| 女人被狂操c到高潮| 国产av在哪里看| 午夜激情欧美在线| 亚洲精品日韩在线中文字幕 | 日韩一区二区视频免费看| 亚洲自偷自拍三级| 国产综合懂色| 国产精品免费一区二区三区在线| 中文字幕人妻熟人妻熟丝袜美| 国内揄拍国产精品人妻在线| 别揉我奶头 嗯啊视频| 男人舔女人下体高潮全视频| 欧洲精品卡2卡3卡4卡5卡区| 亚洲欧美成人综合另类久久久 | 免费在线观看成人毛片| 欧美又色又爽又黄视频| 国产精品一二三区在线看| 免费在线观看影片大全网站| 可以在线观看的亚洲视频| 12—13女人毛片做爰片一| 日韩亚洲欧美综合| 午夜福利高清视频| 国产中年淑女户外野战色| 老熟妇仑乱视频hdxx| 好男人在线观看高清免费视频| 国产极品精品免费视频能看的| 男人的好看免费观看在线视频| 在线观看免费视频日本深夜| 毛片女人毛片| 国产高清视频在线播放一区| 美女 人体艺术 gogo| 日韩av不卡免费在线播放| 日韩 亚洲 欧美在线| 中文字幕av成人在线电影| 国产成人aa在线观看| 老熟妇仑乱视频hdxx| 人妻少妇偷人精品九色| 男女啪啪激烈高潮av片| 中文字幕精品亚洲无线码一区| 日韩一本色道免费dvd| 可以在线观看的亚洲视频| 精品人妻偷拍中文字幕| 日本撒尿小便嘘嘘汇集6| 日本五十路高清| 国产精品美女特级片免费视频播放器| 国内少妇人妻偷人精品xxx网站| 午夜爱爱视频在线播放| 日韩人妻高清精品专区| 最近的中文字幕免费完整| 日韩精品青青久久久久久| 国产精品美女特级片免费视频播放器| 91午夜精品亚洲一区二区三区| 少妇人妻精品综合一区二区 | 男女下面进入的视频免费午夜| 午夜福利成人在线免费观看| 日韩欧美一区二区三区在线观看| 国产 一区 欧美 日韩| 99久久中文字幕三级久久日本| 丝袜喷水一区| 国产一区二区在线av高清观看| 精品久久久久久久人妻蜜臀av| 综合色av麻豆| 欧美人与善性xxx| 天美传媒精品一区二区| 少妇熟女aⅴ在线视频| 亚洲国产精品成人综合色| 亚洲av二区三区四区| 一边摸一边抽搐一进一小说| 亚洲一区二区三区色噜噜| 国产淫片久久久久久久久| 精品人妻偷拍中文字幕| 麻豆av噜噜一区二区三区| 美女大奶头视频| 欧美另类亚洲清纯唯美| 高清日韩中文字幕在线| 天堂网av新在线| 精品久久国产蜜桃| 欧美日韩国产亚洲二区| 欧美激情在线99| av天堂中文字幕网| 99久国产av精品国产电影| 亚洲成人久久性| 三级毛片av免费| av在线观看视频网站免费| 一级av片app| 最新中文字幕久久久久| 国产综合懂色| 亚洲国产欧美人成| 国产免费男女视频| 久久午夜福利片| 在线天堂最新版资源| 国产欧美日韩一区二区精品| 男人舔奶头视频| 又爽又黄无遮挡网站| 久久精品久久久久久噜噜老黄 | 免费看日本二区| 欧美bdsm另类| 久久久a久久爽久久v久久| 少妇的逼好多水| 午夜日韩欧美国产| 国产高清有码在线观看视频| 国产老妇女一区| 国内精品宾馆在线| 午夜福利在线在线| 中文字幕免费在线视频6| 国产私拍福利视频在线观看| 欧美潮喷喷水| 免费看美女性在线毛片视频| 人人妻人人澡人人爽人人夜夜 | 久久草成人影院| 亚洲美女黄片视频| 99在线视频只有这里精品首页| av.在线天堂| 一级毛片电影观看 | 欧美性感艳星| 人人妻人人看人人澡| 免费大片18禁| 变态另类成人亚洲欧美熟女| 亚洲国产精品成人久久小说 | 偷拍熟女少妇极品色| 大香蕉久久网| 久久午夜亚洲精品久久| 亚洲真实伦在线观看| 如何舔出高潮| 国产精品国产三级国产av玫瑰| 免费人成在线观看视频色| 欧美性猛交╳xxx乱大交人| 看免费成人av毛片| 国产精华一区二区三区| 美女高潮的动态| 色在线成人网| 亚洲图色成人| 精品久久久久久久久av| 伊人久久精品亚洲午夜| 一本久久中文字幕| 神马国产精品三级电影在线观看| 精品午夜福利视频在线观看一区| 在线免费观看的www视频| 一级毛片aaaaaa免费看小| 超碰av人人做人人爽久久| 看十八女毛片水多多多| 亚洲国产精品成人久久小说 | 我要看日韩黄色一级片| 国产黄片美女视频| 别揉我奶头~嗯~啊~动态视频| 亚洲乱码一区二区免费版| 亚洲图色成人| 国产精品三级大全| 亚洲国产精品合色在线| 久久午夜亚洲精品久久| 亚洲自拍偷在线| 日本在线视频免费播放| 国产精品三级大全| 黄色配什么色好看| 欧美色视频一区免费| 欧美日本亚洲视频在线播放| 又爽又黄a免费视频| 亚洲国产欧美人成| 少妇高潮的动态图| 别揉我奶头~嗯~啊~动态视频| 国产精品无大码| 色尼玛亚洲综合影院| 精品久久久久久久久av| 欧美绝顶高潮抽搐喷水| 99riav亚洲国产免费| 午夜精品在线福利| 国产av在哪里看| 国产精品永久免费网站| 精品久久久久久久久av| 亚洲国产精品合色在线| 麻豆国产av国片精品| 精品人妻视频免费看| 国产又黄又爽又无遮挡在线| 激情 狠狠 欧美| 亚洲专区国产一区二区| 午夜激情福利司机影院| 久久精品国产亚洲av香蕉五月| 啦啦啦观看免费观看视频高清| 少妇裸体淫交视频免费看高清| 亚洲色图av天堂| 午夜福利视频1000在线观看| 亚洲真实伦在线观看| 成熟少妇高潮喷水视频| 天堂动漫精品| 国产精品乱码一区二三区的特点| 在现免费观看毛片| 18禁黄网站禁片免费观看直播| 精品一区二区三区av网在线观看| 一个人免费在线观看电影| 国产亚洲精品久久久久久毛片| 久久久久性生活片| av免费在线看不卡| 91狼人影院| 男人的好看免费观看在线视频| 国产男靠女视频免费网站| 色尼玛亚洲综合影院| 成人特级av手机在线观看| 国产黄片美女视频| 午夜激情欧美在线| 国产精品久久久久久精品电影| 人人妻人人看人人澡| 亚洲高清免费不卡视频| 欧美又色又爽又黄视频| 中文字幕人妻熟人妻熟丝袜美| 舔av片在线| 国产亚洲精品久久久久久毛片| 国产视频内射| 国产精品国产三级国产av玫瑰| 亚洲性久久影院| 国产亚洲精品久久久com| 日韩欧美精品v在线| 久久人妻av系列| 日韩欧美免费精品| 身体一侧抽搐| 如何舔出高潮| 国产黄a三级三级三级人| 婷婷亚洲欧美| 乱系列少妇在线播放| 午夜a级毛片| 小蜜桃在线观看免费完整版高清| 中国美女看黄片| 人人妻人人澡欧美一区二区| 男女那种视频在线观看| а√天堂www在线а√下载| 两个人的视频大全免费| 午夜福利成人在线免费观看| 国产一区二区亚洲精品在线观看| 免费无遮挡裸体视频| 精品人妻熟女av久视频| 国产蜜桃级精品一区二区三区| 免费av观看视频| 亚洲精品国产av成人精品 | 99久久成人亚洲精品观看| 中国国产av一级| 精品熟女少妇av免费看| 欧美成人免费av一区二区三区| 国产男人的电影天堂91| 欧美不卡视频在线免费观看| 午夜激情福利司机影院| 国产精品,欧美在线| 国产午夜精品论理片| 国产精品嫩草影院av在线观看| 18禁黄网站禁片免费观看直播| 成人一区二区视频在线观看| 少妇猛男粗大的猛烈进出视频 | 激情 狠狠 欧美| 夜夜看夜夜爽夜夜摸| 蜜桃亚洲精品一区二区三区| 国产国拍精品亚洲av在线观看| 国产毛片a区久久久久| 三级毛片av免费| 国产精品免费一区二区三区在线| 国产探花极品一区二区| 麻豆国产av国片精品| 草草在线视频免费看| 午夜日韩欧美国产| 久久国内精品自在自线图片| 看非洲黑人一级黄片| 日韩欧美在线乱码| 男人的好看免费观看在线视频| 精华霜和精华液先用哪个| 麻豆一二三区av精品| 高清毛片免费观看视频网站| 成人三级黄色视频| a级一级毛片免费在线观看| 午夜老司机福利剧场| 无遮挡黄片免费观看| 一级毛片aaaaaa免费看小| 欧美xxxx黑人xx丫x性爽| 无遮挡黄片免费观看| 日韩一区二区视频免费看| 日韩高清综合在线| 18禁黄网站禁片免费观看直播| 麻豆一二三区av精品| 春色校园在线视频观看| 少妇被粗大猛烈的视频| 欧美高清成人免费视频www| 亚洲欧美清纯卡通| 国产一区二区在线观看日韩| 波多野结衣巨乳人妻| 久久国内精品自在自线图片| 一区福利在线观看|